The
text that follows is a PREPRINT.
Please cite as:
Fearnside, P.M. 1996.
Socio-economic factors in the management of tropical forests for carbon. pp.
349-361. In: M.J. Apps & D.T. Price (compiladores) Forest Ecosystems,
Forest Management and the Global Carbon Cycle, NATO ASI Series, Subseries I
"Global Environmental Change," Vol. 40. Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg,Germany.
452 pp.
Copyright: Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg,Germany.
The original publication is available from:
Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg,Germany.
SOCIO-ECONOMIC FACTORS IN THE MANAGEMENT OF TROPICAL
FORESTS FOR CARBON
Philip M. Fearnside
National Institute for Research in the Amazon (INPA)
C. P. 478
69011-970 Manaus, Amazonas
BRAZIL
KEYWORDS/ ABSTRACT: plantations/ silviculture/
logging/ global warming/ greenhouse effect/ carbon sequestration/ tropical
forest management/ carbon dioxide/ climate change mitigation
Tropical forest management response options to global
warming include sustained harvest of timber, extraction of non-timber forest
products, silvicultural plantations, agroforestry, managed secondary succession
and forest maintenance (including both reserve protection and policy changes
affecting deforestation). Socio-economic
factors affect carbon management projects, and vice versa, and can
negate carbon benefits and cause hardship for local populations. Forest maintenance has significant carbon
benefits, as well as other environmental and social advantages. Prerequisites include understanding causes of
deforestation.
I.) TYPES OF FOREST MANAGEMENT FOR CARBON
A.) TIMBER
MANAGEMENT
1.)
Carbon benefits of timber management
Forest
management most commonly refers to timber management. In the tropics, this includes selectively
logging a forest at a specified intensity on a cycle of sufficient duration to
maintain a sustainable flow of harvestable wood. Theoretically, standing biomass of natural
forests under these regimes can keep carbon out of the atmosphere that would
otherwise be released through deforestation.
Some modifications in management practices can contribute to maximizing
the standing stock of biomass, for example, by refraining from thinning stands
of non-commercial species through poison girdling, and by allowing trees to
grow larger before harvesting them.
Programs to reduce logging impacts on unharvested trees also help reduce
emissions that occur through logging damage (Putz and Pinard, 1993). In addition to carbon held in forest biomass
and soil, wood products derived from logging represent pools of carbon kept out
of the atmosphere for periods of years or decades, depending on the end use of
the wood. Hardwoods for furniture and
construction have the longest lifetimes, and therefore the greatest carbon
benefits. Unfortunately, logging
normally functions as a prelude to deforestation regardless of whether it is
stamped as "sustainable management" in official documentation.
2.)
Socio-economic effects on management
Socio-economic
factors can undermine sustainability of management schemes and thereby reduce
their true carbon benefits. Estimates of
the probability of socio-economic or political factors interrupting a carbon
sequestration management program would of necessity be approximate, but this
kind of estimate is nevertheless routinely produced for commercial
decisions. Adjusting carbon calculations
would require weighting each year's expected sequestration by the expected
probability of its taking place in practice, in a manner similar to that used
to adjust for risk and uncertainty in Bayesian calculations of expected
monetary value (e.g. Raiffa, 1968).
Experience indicates that timber management plans have low chances of
actually producing the carbon benefits expected. Accepting calculated carbon benefits for such
proposals at face value is equivalent to expecting to win a million-dollar
lottery by buying a one-dollar ticket,
neglecting to allow for the minuscule probability of winning the prize.
Socio-economic
factors are often critical in preventing management of tropical forests for
timber production from being sustainable in practice, even if silvicultural
parameters indicate technically viability.
Logging roads provide access routes for pioneer farmers who enter to
clear land for agriculture, often outside of government control. Logging firms themselves can sacrifice future
sustained yield by acceleration and/or abandonment of management cycles. Because a number of countries (including
Brazil) require plans for sustainable management as a precondition for granting
logging permits, a strong motivation is set in place for logging firms to
promise the government anything it wants to hear, even if they have no real
intention of following the planned management system over the long term.
Many systems
of sustainable timber management proposed and/or implemented in tropical
countries are technically unpromising.
An example is a proposal for sustainable management announced in 1993 by
the governor of Brazil's State of Amazonas that would cut trees leaving
60-cm-high stumps, to theoretically resprout.
In Malaysia, a country that claims all forest exploitation is already
sustainable, a high probability of forest management systems proving
unsustainable is suggested by a comparison of timber cut with the approximate
amounts that could be produced sustainably in the "permanent production
forests." Wood offtake exceeds
sustainable yield by 39-85% in Peninsular Malaysia, 96-161% in Sabah and
77-236% in Sarawak (calculated from Burgess, 1989: 150). Although overharvesting is likely as at least
part of the explanation for these discrepancies, some wood offtake also comes
from conversion of forest to agriculture.
The argument
is frequently made that sustainable forest management (usually taken to mean logging)
prevents forest from being willfully destroyed.
It is argued that tropical countries must obtain a financial return from
their forests, otherwise they will replace them with agriculture. Logging must therefore be encouraged,
together with research to find uses for woods from more tree species and to
identify sustainable harvest rates and cutting cycle lengths. The potential long-term profits from logging
are expected to result in the countries following these sustainable techniques.
The hope placed
in the beneficial effect of increasing profits to loggers is based on two
expected chains of events. First,
increased profit to loggers results in increased tax revenues, employment, and
other benefits to governments; the governments are therefore expected to ensure
the long-term continuation of these benefits by instituting restrictions on
logging intensity. The second chain of
events expected is that greater profit will motivate the loggers themselves to
take an interest in guaranteeing continuation of the income stream, leading to
investment in long-term production by restriction of logging intensity.
Unfortunately,
these two chains of events represent an incomplete view of the real-world
system. Increasing profit to loggers has
other effects that act in the opposite direction, leading to increase of
logging intensity and destruction of the resource. Increased profit to loggers also leads to an
increase in area logged. Only long-term
profits act to lower logging intensity.
Wood harvested by increasing logging intensity swells short-term profits
to loggers, which motivates loggers to invest in further increasing logging
intensity. This reduces to two opposing
positive feedback relationships. One,
acting through long-term profits, leads logging intensity to be maintained at a
reduced level indicated by the maximum sustainable harvest derived from the
growth rate of the trees; the other, acting through short-term profits, leads
to greater logging intensity. Such a
situation is invariably unstable, leading to one extreme or the other. Which way the balance goes depends on the
strength of the forces on each side.
However, it is not a mystery as to which side is the stronger, as
indicated by the obvious lack of commercial-scale forest management systems in
the world today. Poore et al.
(1989: xiv) surveyed management throughout the tropics and concluded that
"the extent of tropical moist forest which is being deliberately managed
at an operational scale for the sustainable production of timber is, on a world
scale, negligible."
The root of
the problem lies in the rapid discounting of future returns applied in
financial calculations, leading to decisions to harvest natural populations at
unsustainable rates. This occurs when
the discount rate is more than twice the maximum reproductive potential of the
population (see Clark, 1973, 1976 for mathematical proof). Growth rates of tropical trees are controlled
by biological factors having nothing to do with rates of financial return
obtainable on investments in other parts of the economy. These biological limitations place
sustainable management for timber at an inherent disadvantage (Fearnside,
1989a).
The contrast
between Southeast Asia and Amazonia indicates a lack of factual basis for the
theory that increasing profits to loggers leads to sustainable management. For various reasons, forests of Southeast
Asia are commercially more valuable and easier to manage than those in Amazonia
(Fearnside, 1989a). If raising the
commercial value of forest leads to sustainable management, one would expect
Southeast Asia to be a paradise of sustainability. On the contrary, Southeast Asian forests are
being destroyed more rapidly than those in Amazonia precisely because Asian
forests are more valuable. Higher value
increases motivation to destroy the forest more than it increases motivation to
sustain production.
In addition
to the problem of discount rates, most forest in Brazilian Amazonia is
effectively an open-access resource, repeating the tragedy of the commons at
each site brought under exploitation.
Sawmills in Amazonia can be moved when forest is exhausted in any
particular place. Many sawmill
operations migrated from Espírito Santo to northern Mato Grosso after the
Atlantic forest dwindled in their former home (only about 4% of the Atlantic
forest remains). Sawmills are now moving
from northern Mato Grosso to other parts of the Amazon region.
The danger
of forestry management plans being used to legitimize activities that in
reality will lead to destruction of forest (and to greenhouse gas emissions) is increased by the presence of
corruption. Papua New Guinea is the
best-documented example (Marshall, 1990).
The political value of offering forests for destructive use also contravenes
any management scenario that might be devised on the basis of data on
silviculture and markets. Making global
warming response proposals on the assumption that corruption and local politics
are irrelevant is exceedingly naive.
Corruption,
although the subject of minimal quantitative study and little open discussion,
is a critical socio-economic factor in determining the effectiveness of global
warming response options in the forest sector.
Why, for example, is Costa Rica the focus of so much more international
interest for carbon offset projects than Zare, even though Zare is a much more important country in terms of
tropical forests? The notoriety of Zare for corruption (e.g. Witte, 1993) is surely an
important part of the answer.
3.)
Socio-economic impacts of management
Timber
management precludes use of the land for agriculture. This means that agricultural populations must
have alternative locations to cultivate, or must turn to other professions to
support themselves. It is worth noting
that large areas of already cleared land exist in Brazilian Amazonia, and that
the tendency to establish agricultural settlement areas in forests on public
lands is explained by political expediency rather than physical limits. The path of least resistance is to decree
settlement areas on public land, most of which is forested, rather than to
expropriate private lands. Even in other
parts of the tropics, where agricultural populations are proportionally much
larger, the argument that maintaining native forest represents a threat to the
poor is fallacious (Fearnside, 1993a).
4.)
Recommended role of timber management
Timber
management offers some opportunities for carbon offsets, as in reducing logging
impact on the remainder of the forest.
However, the more central question of promoting expansion of timber
management into presently undisturbed areas requires considerable caution. In practice, plans for sustainable management
of tropical forests for timber frequently result instead in destruction of
forest. Better results may be obtainable
by trying to substitute plantation-grown wood as much as possible for natural
forest logging. Rather than by promoting
timber management, the key to maintaining carbon stocks in natural forests is likely
to lie in designing systems to provide compensation for the environmental
services they provide, including carbon storage. Maintenance of standing forest as a form of
management will be discussed later.
B.)
NON-TIMBER FOREST PRODUCTS (NTFPs)
1.)
Carbon benefits of management for NTFPs
Non-timber
forest products, or NTFPs, are an important source of revenue and of unique
products. Most have the great advantage
over timber of not destroying or significantly damaging forest when extracted. Proposals for managing forests for these
products are of two types: extractive reserves, where only NTFPs may be
harvested, and mixed management systems where both timber and NTFPs are
exploited. Brazil has a system of extractive
reserves in which populations of rubber tappers and other extractivists are
granted use rights to forest on the condition that only NTFPs be removed, with
an allowance for a limited amount of subsistence agriculture (Allegretti, 1990;
Fearnside, 1989b). The proposal for
extractive reserves originated with the extractivists themselves, rather than
being handed down from above as is the norm in Amazonian development
planning. The financial value of the
NTFPs sold from the reserves, while very important to sustaining the
extractivist population, is not the rationale for the government's creation of
these reserves. The reserves are
justified as a means of maintaining the forest for its environmental functions,
which is why the reserves are created by the Brazilian Institute for the Environment
and Renewable Natural Resources (IBAMA) rather than by the National Institute
for Colonization and Agrarian Reform (INCRA).
Brazil's extractive reserves, important as they are, occupy a minuscule
fraction of the forest area--about 0.6% as of 1993 (Brazil, IBGE, 1993:
116-125). Carbon stored in the reserves
is one argument for their expansion (Brown et al., 1992).
Mixed
management systems for timber and NTFPs have been initiated in several
locations, including an experimental system under study by the International
Tropical Timber Organization in Brazil's state of Acre. NTFPs can be critical factor in making
combined timber/NTFP management financially attractive (Perez et al.,
1993: 53).
2.)
Socio-economic effects on management
When NTFPs
are harvested by a resident population, as in the case of Brazil's extractive
reserves, these people are an integral part of the management system. This has the advantage of providing a
dedicated interest group to defend the forest against encroachment. It also implies a certain level of impact on
the forest through expansion of the area each household uses for subsistence
agriculture and through increase in the number of households through
reproduction or immigration of population.
The population is also subject to the ever-present temptation to produce
cash crops from agriculture or to sell timber.
How these forces are handled by local associations of extractivists and
by government agencies that oversee reserves will have important impacts both
on the management of the existing reserves and on the extent to which this land
use eventually expands. The land tenure
arrangement of Brazil's extractive reserves removes the possibility of land
becoming a commodity rather than an input to production; were this precaution not taken, financial
returns of extractive use would compare unfavorably with deforestation (Hecht,
1992: 395). Since the first extractive
reserve was created in 1988, the results of this land use have been much better
in terms of maintaining forests, with their carbon stocks, than have common
alternatives such as logging and/or cattle ranching.
3.)
Socio-economic impacts of management
Management
of forests for NTFPs can have positive effects on local populations, as
collection occupies a substantial amount of labor and more financial returns
accrue to the local population than is usually the case with timber. In the case of extractive reserves in Brazil,
the social organization required to request, establish and manage the reserves
has numerous collateral benefits for the population involved by allowing them
to improve other social services, such as education and health care.
4.)
Recommended role of NTFPs
Collection
and management of NTFPs are beneficial additions to timber management
schemes. However, intense controversy
arises when the reverse suggestion is made: to add timber harvesting to
projects designed for sustainable extraction of NTFPs. This is because, in practice, adding timber
harvesting to extractive reserve management plans can lead to destruction or
degradation of forest for the same reasons that forests are destroyed or
degraded through pure timber management.
In Brazil, the National Council of Rubber Tappers (CNS) has therefore
opposed moves to allow timber management in extractive reserves. Allowing timber harvesting undermines the
principal argument upon which the creation of extractive reserves is based,
which is environmental benefits of the reserves rather than commodity
production.
C.)
SILVICULTURAL PLANTATIONS
1.)
Carbon benefits of plantations
Silvicultural
plantations are classified as "managed forests" by the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) (Kupfer and Karimanzira,
1991). Plantations have been the focus
of most response options undertaken in the forestry sector in tropical
countries, such as those funded by the Global Environment Facility (GEF). Plantations maintain some carbon in standing
biomass of planted trees and also direct carbon to wood product pools.
In the humid
tropics the amount of carbon held in standing stock is invariably much less
than native forest, but more than in uses such as agriculture or pasture. The greatest potential carbon benefits of
plantations, however, are by means of fossil fuel substitution when biomass is
used as fuelwood, charcoal or, in the future, liquid biofuels such as methanol
(Fearnside, In press).
2.)
Socio-economic effects on plantations
Socio-economic
factors can act in various ways to cause "leakage" from plantation
projects, or the negation of carbon benefits by events that the project sets in
motion beyond its defined borders. One
example is provided by the controversy surrounding plantations that the World
Bank is considering funding to supply charcoal to pig iron smelters in Brazil's
Grande Carajás area. Private pulp mills
that are being set up in the area are likely to offer a higher price for
plantation-produced wood than can be expected from charcoal makers. Subsidized plantation owners would be likely
to sell their wood to pulp mills. The
pig iron smelters, whose licensing and access to subsidies are legitimized by
the plantation plans, would then obtain charcoal made from native forest wood,
provoking carbon emissions and other impacts.
The inherent attraction of free wood from native forest makes charcoal
manufacture for pig iron a continual threat to remaining forests in eastern
Amazonia (Anderson, 1990; Fearnside, 1989c).
Population
displacement can lead to "leakage" of carbon benefits. If former residents of plantation areas move
to clear new plots in tropical forest, they will provoke substantial carbon
emissions. This was one of the concerns
affecting a proposed carbon offset plantation in Ecuador, from which the Global
Environment Facility withdrew its commitment of support in 1993.
Markets for
wood products exert a strong influence on plantation operations and their
carbon benefits, including "leakage" of the benefits of carbon
offsets in wood product pools. This is
because expansion of plantations at one location will subsequently increase
global supplies of wood products, thereby making prices lower than they
otherwise would be, and at other unsubsidized locations would cause marginal
plantations to be abandoned and/or would discourage initiation of new
plantations. To the extent that the
economic "invisible hand" functions as expected, no net global gain
in carbon stocks would result from subsidizing plantations other than the small
gain from time lags as the subsidized plantations grow prior to their first
harvest, and as additions to wood product pools and areas of unprofitable
unsubsidized plantations remain in place for a time while a new equilibrium is
established.
3.)
Socio-economic impacts of plantations
Conversion
of land to plantations can deprive local populations of their means of support
(Barnett, 1992). Plantations can involve
displacement of local populations occupying the sites prior to initiating the
schemes. Depending on the social system
surrounding use of plantation output, socio-economic conditions that develop
can be highly undesirable. In the case
of plantations for charcoal in Brazil, the industry's competitiveness depends
on maintaining most of the labor pool under sub-human conditions through a
system of debt slavery (Pachauski, 1994; Ribeiro, 1994; Sutton, 1994).
Plantations
in some parts of the world take over commons that are traditionally used by
local populations. In India, for
example, "social forestry" programs have often benefitted wealthy
landholders and paper mills at the expense of rural poor (Centre for Science
and Environment, 1985: 51‑62; Shiva et al., 1985). These plantations often occupy public
roadsides or unplanted portions of private landholdings that traditionally
provide firewood and animal fodder to poor villagers. In India, the choice of Eucalyptus
deprives the poor of useful supplementary products such as foliage for fodder
(Saxena, 1989: 82). Poor people have
sometimes reacted by ripping Eucalyptus seedlings out of the nurseries
(Joyce, 1988). India's social forestry
program was launched with the avowed objective of helping the poor (see
Eckholm, 1979: 48‑56).
In Thailand
plantations on common lands could result in eviction of hundreds of thousands
of people if industrial plans are fully realized (Koohacharoen, 1992). Employment in plantations can only support
about one local family per 20 ha of trees, according to an estimate by Royal
Dutch Shell in reference to its planned 200,000 ha of plantations in Thailand
(Lohmann, 1990: 10). Silviculture
expansion in Thailand illustrates well the gulf between analyses of such
programs from the standpoint of carbon benefits as opposed to their impact on
the local population: the Thai program has been lauded as a model for carbon
sequestration throughout the tropics because of its low establishment costs
(Dixon et al., 1994).
4.)
Recommended role of plantations
Plantations
have a legitimate place in efforts to combat global warming. The place of plantations is constrained,
however, by the comparative costs and benefits of other options, such as
maintenance of native tropical forests, and by the socio-economic impacts of
plantations. For a variety of reasons,
the tendency has been to overestimate the carbon benefits of plantations and underestimate
their social impacts, while the reverse tendency applies to forest maintenance
calculations (see Fearnside, In press).
D.)
AGROFORESTRY
1.)
Carbon benefits of agroforestry
Agroforestry
refers to the combination of trees (either planted or unplanted) with other
trees, arable farming, or grazing. This
land use maintains a larger stock of carbon than pasture or arable
farming. However, if native tropical
forest is sacrificed to implant agroforestry, then the effect on carbon stores
would be negative. A large carbon credit
is often claimed for agroforestry on the basis of its assumed role in slowing
deforestation. These benefits are often
exaggerated, because much deforestation is not related to subsistence farming,
especially in Brazil (Fearnside, 1992a).
2.)
Socio-economic effects on agroforestry
The extent
to which agroforestry can be expanded is severely limited by markets for the
products. Were any significant portion
of Brazilian Amazonia converted to agroforestry, for example, markets would be
quickly saturated. Input requirements
also limit expansion (Fearnside, 1992a).
3.)
Socio-economic impacts of agroforestry
Agroforestry
projects generally have greater benefits for local population than do
silvicultural plantations of trees such as Eucalyptus. Agroforestry systems have the great advantage
of being appropriate for small farmers and of producing a variety of products
throughout the year. This maximizes
direct use of the products and use of family labor. The diversity of crop species planted
minimizes effects of swings in commodity market prices and risks of biological
problems (such as insect outbreaks or disease).
Offering a stable economic base for small farmers is an important
objective for social reasons, independent of environmental benefits.
4.)
Recommended role of agroforestry
Agroforestry
has real carbon benefits. The priority attached to it for carbon sequestration,
however, depends strongly on the forces underlying deforestation in each
location. In Brazilian Amazonia, the
priority of promoting agroforestry would be low as an anti-deforestation
measure (Fearnside, 1992a).
E.) MANAGED SECONDARY SUCCESSION
1.) Carbon benefits of managed
succession
Managed secondary forests have been
suggested as an option for use of degraded lands, such as the growing areas of
abandoned cattle pastures in Brazilian Amazonia. The carbon store in managed secondary
succession is greater than what would be present if the secondary forests were
cut for arable crops or pasture.
However, immediate cutting of secondary vegetation is often not the most
likely alternative in the absence of management programs.
2.) Socio-economic effects on management
"Management" of secondary succession implies a
reclassification of this vegetation from an "unproductive" to a
"productive" status. Such a
reclassification, both in the legal sense and in the public relations sense,
can be very useful to firms (and nations) eager to improve their image as
destroyers of tropical forests. In
Brazil, ranch owners are anxious not to have their abandoned pastures
considered as "unproductive" because land so classified is subject to
higher taxes, and because it increases chances that their land will be taken by
the government for agrarian reform. If
secondary forest can be reclassified as "managed" with a minimal
investment, it would be much cheaper as a means of maintaining claim to these
large land holdings than would the most common alternative at present:
investing in either reclearing and burning or bulldozing and fertilizing to
replant cattle pasture. These
considerations would be likely to result in a willingness to embrace managed
secondary succession projects greatly in excess of what might be justified by
expected financial returns from selling the commodities produced, or even from
expected environmental return from carbon storage.
3.) Socio-economic impacts of management
Secondary forests can produce biomass and other products useful
to humans (Brown and Lugo, 1990). This
option has the advantage of requiring little investment and physical
inputs. In Brazilian Amazonia, however,
it should be remembered that most secondary forests are growing in degraded
cattle pastures and produce less in all respects than do similar forests in
shifting cultivation fallows.
An important issue in deciding policy on encouraging different
land-use systems is the question of who is to be benefited. Most secondary forests in Brazilian Amazonia
are in the hands of large ranchers, many of whom have long enjoyed generous
government subsidies for clearing forest and planting pasture. Should these
same ranchers receive additional subsidies?
The prospect of granting additional subsidies to these landholders to
manage the secondary succession that now occupies their degraded pasture sites
implies an official commitment to perpetuating the existing highly skewed
distribution of land tenure in the region.
At the time of the last agricultural census, 62.3% of private land in
the region was in properties over 1000 ha in area, while only 11.1% was in
properties under 100 ha in area (Brazil, IBGE, 1989: 297). The socio-economic impacts of this
distribution of land tenure are many (Fearnside, 1985).
4.) Recommended role of managed succession
Any promotion of managed succession in Brazilian Amazonia should
be restricted to small farmers. Better
options exist for carbon storage through maintenance of standing native forest.
F.) MAINTENANCE OF STANDING FOREST
1.) Carbon benefits of forest maintenance
Capturing the value of environmental services of standing
forest, including the value of storing carbon, must be viewed as a form of
forest management. In addition to their
role in averting global warming, forests have great value (for which no one is
paying) in maintaining biodiversity and, in the case of Brazil, in supplying
the hydrological cycle that provides rainfall to much of the country. Measures designed to slow deforestation can
easily be justified on the basis of carbon benefits (Fearnside, 1992b). These measures also have socio-economic
consequences.
2.) Socio-economic effects on forest maintenance
Socio-economic factors can lead to "leakage," negating
the benefits of forest protection achieved through reserve establishment and
through some types of deforestation reduction policy changes. If establishing a reserve simply means that
potential deforesters move elsewhere to continue clearing, then little or no
net carbon gain is achieved. The
benefits of forest maintenance proposals can therefore only be assessed at the
level of programs, nations, or the world--not with project-level analyses. Little progress has been made on estimating
the most likely costs of forest maintenance, let alone assessing the
uncertainty attached to such an estimate.
Deforestation is strongly influenced by government policy decisions that
have little direct connection with financial costs (Fearnside, 1987).
Socio-economic factors increase uncertainty of both costs and
expected benefits of forest maintenance projects. This is true of both reserve establishment
and programs to reduce deforestation, but is especially important for the
latter. Unlike plantations, for which
accumulated experience makes the costs and benefits relatively well known,
forest maintenance is fraught with unknowns.
Many depend on the outcome of struggles between opposing political and
economic interest groups. For example,
if heavy taxes were applied to speculative profits from land sales in order to
remove one of the primary forces behind deforestation, those expecting to
realize such profits would surely object.
The fact that the main impediments to forest maintenance are in the
realm of political will rather than financial expense makes this option
attractive from the monetary cost-effectiveness standpoint for carbon
offsets. The same fact also explains why
more has not been done to slow deforestation.
Political barriers, while they must not be underestimated, should not
simply be accepted as immutable. The
loss that forest destruction represents needs to be translated into a force of
appropriate strength directed at changing the key policies that lie within the
government's control (see Fearnside, 1989d).
3.) Socio-economic impacts of forest maintenance
One of the most persistent myths about deforestation in
Brazilian Amazonia is that it is primarily done by the poor. In 1990 and 1991, only 30.5% of the clearing
was done by small farmers (defined in Brazilian Amazonia as having less than
100 ha of land), while almost 70% was done by medium and large ranchers
(Fearnside, 1993b). Distribution of
property sizes alone explains 74% of the variance in deforestation rates among
the nine Amazonian states. This means
that deforestation in Brazil could be slowed tremendously at minimal social
cost--up to 70% without even touching any small farmers. It should be recognized that Brazil is
different from most other tropical areas, and that such great gains could not
be so easily achieved elsewhere without either inflicting hardship on the poor
or providing alternative means for their support.
Employment is often the first question raised in discussions of
forest preservation in protected areas.
Would it not be better to hand out the land as agricultural lots to
support part of the unemployed population?
The answer to employment depends very much on what is to be done with
money that is brought in by the environmental services of the forest. If the sums involved are large, as the true
importance of the services implies they should be, then there is substantial
scope for creating employment. One form
of employment is guarding the reserves themselves. It is important to realize that this form of
employment can only sustain a limited number of people, and that these are not
the same people who would receive lots if the land were to be handed out for
agricultural settlement instead of being made into a reserve. However, for the true "local"
inhabitants (rubber tappers, etc.) already in the interior, this is an
important option. Often these people
would not have other opportunities for employment. Additional rural employment could be generated
in scientific research, for example, if programs were established to
botanically collect, map, and measure trees in large areas in the reserves,
followed by monitoring of tree mortality, regeneration, phenology and other
factors. In addition, population
distribution in Brazilian Amazonia is now predominantly urban. Employment in urban centers is, in some ways,
easier to create. Activities linked to
forest maintenance would be preferable.
For example, laboratories could be set up in Amazonian cities to analyze
plant secondary compounds obtained from forest reserves.
4.)
Recommended role of forest maintenance
The large potential carbon benefits,
parallel benefits of other environmental services, and relatively low financial
requirements of forest maintenance all indicate this as the top priority for
forest management for carbon. If done
with a view to maximizing benefits for local populations, socio-economic
effects could be positive, both in the short and long term. Policy changes to slow deforestation would
have more immediate payoffs in reducing carbon emissions than establishing
protected areas. A prerequisite for
evaluating benefits of such changes is a sound understanding of causes of
deforestation and incorporation of this understanding into models capable of
generating reliable forecasts under different policy scenarios.
II.) THE PLACE OF
SOCIO-ECONOMIC FACTORS IN CARBON OFFSETS
Socio-economic factors constrain the potential scale to which
forest management options for carbon can expand. These factors also affect the carbon benefits
if the projects are successful, and the probability of success. Much depends on social costs of the
management schemes. Insufficient
attention to socio-economic factors has resulted in a tendency for carbon
proposals to underestimate social costs in some cases (such as plantations) and
overestimate them in others (such as controlling deforestation in Brazilian
Amazonia). The benefits of plantations
are often overestimated because "leakage" caused by socio-economic
factors is ignored. Tendencies in
evaluating forestry response options are summarized in Table 1.
TABLE 1: TENDENCIES IN EVALUATING FORESTRY RESPONSE
OPTIONS
Response options
Carbon Poten- Prob-
Social
benefits tial ability
costs
if
scale of
successful success
------------------------------------------------------------
Timber management + 0 ++ 0
Non-wood products - + 0 0
Plantations + + 0 -
Agroforestry + + 0 0
Managed succession + 0 0 0
Forest maintenance:
a.) Protected areas + + + 0
b.) Deforestation - - + +
reduction policies
------------------------------------------------------------
+ = overestimated
- = underestimated
0 = OK
Most of the foregoing discussion has dealt with negative aspects
of relations between socio-economic factors and forest management: the
impediments socio-economic concerns pose to management and the detrimental
effects of management on local populations.
One might be led to believe that management of native forest and
establishment of plantations should automatically be ruled out as global
warming response options. I hasten to
add that these impediments and impacts are only part of the suite of
considerations that must be weighed in judging proposed expansion of these
activities. Also important are the
supply of each nation's domestic demand for wood products, the avoidance of
global warming impacts, and the impacts of other alternatives for supplying
wood and combating the greenhouse effect.
While response options in the forestry sector can have harmful
socio-economic impacts, it should never be forgotten that inaction also has
impacts. Impacts of global warming are
not restricted to damaging the economies of a few rich countries, even if this
constitutes a major motivation behind the willingness of industrialized nations
to invest in response options around the world, including forestry options in
the tropics. Effects of global warming
will also be felt each time a tropical storm hits the mudflats of Bangladesh or
a drought hits famine-prone areas of Africa.
Global warming could result in millions of deaths in these places over
the next century (Daily and Ehrlich, 1990).
Global warming must be addressed on a scale sufficient to solve
the problem: it is not reasonable to conclude that all possible countermeasures
have undesirable effects, therefore we will do nothing. Forestry responses in the tropics cannot
substitute for the large reductions that must occur in emissions from fossil
fuels burned in the industrialized countries.
The interest of industrialized countries in funding management in
tropical forests as a response to the greenhouse effect offers an opportunity
for tropical countries to achieve a variety of environmental and social goals
in addition to those related to avoiding global warming impacts. However, extreme care is needed, both on the
part of international funders and recipient nations, to insure that forest activities
implemented under the banner of global warming abatement do not provoke
unacceptable socio-economic impacts.
Because global warming responses have social as well as financial costs,
it is essential that there be international equity in sharing social
costs. It is not enough for the wealthy
nations to be willing to pay a large part of the financial costs of combating
global warming: they must also be willing to accept some of the social costs.
III.) CONCLUSIONS
Forestry responses to global warming in the tropics can have
substantial socio-economic consequences, some are beneficial to local
populations but many are detrimental.
Socio-economic factors also strongly influence the attractiveness of
different response options and the likelihood of their achieving expected
levels of carbon benefit. In general,
slowing deforestation has been underrated while other options have been
overrated as a means of countering global warming. Plantations have greater social impacts and
less economic benefits than many proponents believe. Slowing deforestation has substantial
ancillary benefits in maintaining other environmental services of the
forest. In the case of Brazil, most
deforestation is done by cattle ranchers, and great reduction of clearing could
be achieved with no effect on feeding local populations. In many other parts of the tropics, where the
role of small farmers is greater, alternative means of supporting local
populations must accompany programs designed to slow forest loss. Decision-making on management of tropical
forests for carbon must give proper weight to socio-economic factors if
forestry projects are to benefit local people and to function effectively to
avert global warming.
IV.) ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
Funds from the Pew Scholars Program in Conservation and the
Environment were used for travel in Asia.
I thank S. V. Wilson and four anonymous reviewers for comments on the
manuscript.
V.) REFERENCES
Allegretti
M. H. (1990) Extractive reserves: An alternative for reconciling development
and environmental conservation in Amazonia. In: Alternatives to
Deforestation: Steps toward Sustainable Use of Amazonian Rain Forest (ed.
A. B. Anderson). Columbia University Press, New York, pp. 252-264.
Anderson
A. B. (1990) Smokestacks in the rainforest: Industrial development and
deforestation in the Amazon Basin. World Devel. 18, 1556-1570.
Barnett
A. (1992) Desert of Trees: The Environmental and Social Impacts of
Large-Scale Tropical Reforestation in Response to Global Climate Change.
Friends of the Earth, London, 62 p.
Brazil,
IBGE (Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística). (1989) Anuário
Estatístico do Brasil 1989. IBGE, Rio de Janeiro, 716 p.
Brazil,
IBGE (Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística). (1993) Recursos Naturais
e Meio Ambiente. IBGE, Rio de Janeiro, 154 p.
Brown
I. F., Nepstad D. C., Pires I. O., Luz L. M. and Alechandre A.S. (1992) Carbon
storage and land use in extractive reserves, Acre, Brazil. Envir. Cons. 19,
307-315.
Brown
S. and Lugo A. E. (1990) Tropical secondary forests. J. Trop. Ecol. 6,
1-32.
Burgess
P. F. (1989) Asia. In: No Timber without Trees: Sustainability in the
Tropical Forest (eds. D. Poore, P. F. Burgess, J. Palmer, S. Ritbergen and
T. Synnott). Earthscan, London, pp. 117-153.
Centre
for Science and Environment (1985) Social forestry. In: The State of India's
Environment 1984‑85: The Second Citizens' Report. Centre for Science
and Environment, New Delhi, India, pp. 51‑62.
Clark
C. B. (1973) The economics of overexploitation. Science 181, 630‑634.
Clark
C. B. (1976) Mathematical Bioeconomics: The Optimal Management of Renewable
Resources. Wiley‑Interscience, New York, 352 p.
Daily
G. C. and Ehrlich P. R. (1990) An exploratory model of the impact of rapid
climate change on the world food situation. Proc. Royal Soc. London (Biol.)
241, 232-244.
Dixon
R. K., Winjum J. K., Andrasko K. J., Lee J. J. and Schroeder P. E. (1994)
Integrated land-use systems: Assessment of promising agroforest and alternative
land-use practices to enhance carbon conservation and sequestration. Clim.
Chng. 27, 71-92.
Eckholm
E. (1979) Planting for the future: Forestry for human needs. Worldwatch
Paper No. 26. Worldwatch Institute, Washington, D.C., 64 p.
Fearnside
P. M. (1985) Agriculture in Amazonia. In: Key Environments: Amazonia
(eds. G. T. Prance and T. E. Lovejoy) Pergamon, Oxford, U.K., pp. 393‑418.
Fearnside
P. M. (1987) Causes of Deforestation in
the Brazilian Amazon. In: The Geophysiology of Amazonia: Vegetation and
Climate Interactions. (ed. R. F. Dickinson) John Wiley & Sons, New
York. pp. 37‑61.
Fearnside
P. M. (1989a) Forest management in Amazonia: The need for new criteria in
evaluating development options. For. Ecol. Manage. 27, 61‑79.
Fearnside
P. M. (1989b) Extractive reserves in Brazilian Amazonia: An opportunity to
maintain tropical rain forest under sustainable use. BioScience 39,
387‑393.
Fearnside
P. M. (1989c) The Charcoal of Carajás: Pig‑iron smelting threatens the
forests of Brazil's Eastern Amazon Region. Ambio 18, 141‑143.
Fearnside
P. M. (1989d) A prescription for slowing deforestation in Brazilian Amazonia. Environment
31, 16-20, 39-40.
Fearnside
P. M. (1992a) Agroforestry in Brazil's Amazonian development policy: The role
and limits of a potential use for degraded lands. In: Desenvolvimento Sustentável
nos Trópicos Úmidos (ed. L. E. Aragón) Associação de Universidades
Amazônicas (UNAMAZ)/Universidade Federal do Pará (UFPA), Belém, Brazil, pp.
417-433.
Fearnside
P. M. (1992b) Greenhouse Gas Emissions from Deforestation in the Brazilian
Amazon. Carbon Emissions and Sequestration in Forests: Case Studies from
Developing Countries. Volume 2. Climate Change Division, Environmental
Protection Agency, Washington, D.C. and Energy and Environment Division,
Lawrence Berkeley Laboratory, University of California, Berkeley, 73 p.
Fearnside
P. M. (1993a) Forests or fields: A response to the theory that tropical forest
conservation poses a threat to the poor. Land Use Policy 10,
108-121.
Fearnside
P. M. (1993b) Deforestation in Brazilian Amazonia: The effect of population and
land tenure. Ambio 22, 537-545.
Fearnside
P. M. In press. Global warming response options in Brazil's forest sector:
Comparison of project-level costs and benefits. Biomass and Bioenergy.
Hecht
S. B. (1992) Valuing land uses in Amazonia:
Colonist agriculture, cattle, and petty extraction in comparative
perspective. In: Conservation of
Neotropical Forests: Working from
Traditional Resource Use (eds. K. H. Redford and C. Padoch). Columbia
University Press, New York, pp. 379-399.
Joyce
C. (1988) The tree that caused a riot. New Sci. 18, 95-100.
Koohacharoen
O. (1992) Commercial reforestation policy. In: The Future of People and
Forests in Thailand after the Logging Ban (eds. P. Leungaramsri and N.
Rajesh). Project for Ecological Recovery, Bangkok, Thailand, pp. 56-78.
Kupfer
D. and Karimanzira R. (1991) Agriculture, forestry, and other human activities.
In: Climate Change: The IPCC Response Strategies, IPCC, Island Press,
Covelo, CA, pp. 73-127.
Lohmann
L. (1990) Commercial tree plantations in Thailand: Deforestation by any other
name. The Ecologist 20, 9-17.
Lugo
A. E. and Brown S. (1986) Brazil's Amazon forest and the global carbon problem.
Interciencia 11, 57-58.
Marshall
G. (1990) The political economy of logging: The Barnett inquiry into corruption
in the Papua New Guinea timber industry. The Ecologist 20,
174-181.
Pachauski
F. (1994) "Trabalha, escravo." Isto É (Brasília) 4 May 1994,
pp. 32-35.
Perez
M. R., Sayer J. A. and Jehoram S.C. (1993) El Extractivismo en América
Latina. World Conservation Union (IUCN), Gland, Switzerland, 99 p.
Poore
D., Burgess P. F., Palmer J., Ritbergen S. and Synnott T. (1989) No Timber
without Trees: Sustainability in the Tropical Forest. Earthscan, London,
U.K., 252 p.
Putz
F. E. and Pinard M. A. (1993) Reduced-impact logging as a carbon-offset method.
Cons. Biol. 7, 755-757.
Raiffa
H. (1968) Decision Analysis: Introductory Lectures on Choices under
Uncertainty. Addison‑Wesley, Reading, MA, 312 p.
Ribeiro
A. Jr. (1994) "Carvoeiros são 'escravos' em MG." A Folha de São
Paulo 31 July 1994, pp. 1-1 and 1-12.
Saxena
N. C. (1989) Forestry and rural development. South Asia Journal 3,
59-89.
Shiva
V., Bandyopadhyay J. and Jayal N. D. (1985) Afforestation in India: Problems
and strategies. Ambio 14, 329-333.
Sutton
A. (1994) Slavery in Brazil--A Link in the Chain of Modernization.
Anti-Slavery International, London.
Witte
J. (1993) Deforestation in Zaire:
Logging and landlessness.
In: The Struggle for Land and
the Fate of the Forests. (eds. M. Colchester and L. Lohmann). Zed Books,
London, U.K., pp. 179-197.