The
text that follows is a PREPRINT.
Please cite as:
Fearnside, P.M. 2005. Global implications of Amazon frontier
settlement: Carbon, Kyoto and the role of Amazonian deforestation. pp. 36-64. In:
A. Hall (ed.) Global Impact, Local
Action: New Environmental Policy in Latin America.
University of London, School of Advanced Studies, Institute for the Study of
the Americas, London, U.K. 321 pp.
ISBN
1-900039-56-7
Copyright:
University
of London, School of Advanced Studies, Institute for the Study of the Americas,
The
original publication is available from University of London, School of Advanced Studies,
Institute for the Study of the Americas, London, U.K.
GLOBAL
IMPLICATIONS OF AMAZON FRONTIER SETTLEMENT: CARBON, KYOTO AND THE ROLE OF
AMAZONIAN DEFORESTATION
Philip M. Fearnside
Instituto Nacional de
Pesquisas da Amazônia (INPA)
(National Institute for Research
in the Amazon)
Av. André Araújo, 2936
Caixa Postal 478
69011-970 Manaus ‑
Amazonas
BRAZIL
FAX: +55-92-642-8909
Email: PMFEARN@INPA.GOV.BR
.
Contribution for: In: A. Hall (ed.) Global Impact,
Local Action: New Environmental Policy in Latin America. University of
London, Institute of Latin American Studies (ILAS),
22
January 2004.
INTRODUCTION
Land use and land-use change in
Amazonia contribute to global climatic change in several ways. Climatic changes
affected by deforestation include decrease of rainfall due to the decrease of
the recycling of water, especially in the dry season. Water recycled by the
Amazon forest makes a substantial contribution to rainfall in the central and
southern parts of the country in the months of December and January, which is
the critical time for refilling hydroelectric reservoirs in that area
(Fearnside, 2004a). Deforestation also makes a contribution to global warming.
Brazil’s Amazonian deforestation released net committed emissions of 258-270 million tonnes of CO2-equivalent carbon
annually over the 1988-1994 period. In 2002, considering the preliminary official
estimate of the rate of deforestation of 25.5 thousand km2/yr and
median values for trace gases, the net committed emissions (i.e., with the regrowth of secondary vegetation
already deducted) totaled 442 million tons of carbon--an astronomical amount.
Gases are released by deforestation through burning and decomposition of
biomass, and from soil, logging, hydroelectric dams, cattle and the repeated
burning of pasture and secondary forests.
Burning also affects the formation
of clouds and affects the chemistry of the atmosphere in several ways in
addition to the greenhouse effect. The
contribution of forest loss to these climatic changes, together with other
global changes such as biodiversity loss, provides the basis for a new strategy
to sustain the population of the area. Instead of destroying the forest to
produce some kind of merchandise, as is the current pattern, this alternative
strategy would use forest maintenance to generate cash flows based on the
environmental services of the forest, in other words, the value of avoiding the
impacts that result from destruction of the forest (Fearnside, 1997a). The
value of avoided deforestation in combating global warming is closer than other
environmental services to becoming an alternative to deforestation in the
region’s economy. However, controversies surround the inclusion of avoided
deforestation in the Kyoto Protocol’s Clean Development Mechanism (CDM), and
credit for this measure has now been barred until 2013. As a matter of disclosure, I have been
arguing since 1982 for reducing deforestation as a means of mitigating global
warming, and since 1983 a large part of my professional efforts have been
devoted to filling the gaps in data and analysis needed to quantify
deforestation emissions and make avoided deforestation a source of value for
supporting the Amazonian population.
Therefore, although I will attempt to explain the positions of all
sides, readers should not expect neutrality.
Saving
tropical forests as a measure to mitigate the greenhouse effect divides the
environmental movement. The divisions among non-governmental organizations
(NGOs) are as large as the differences among national governments. While the
debate is frequently couched in scientific terms with appeals to high universal
principles, the positions of the different parties are better understood in
terms of hidden agendas. In the case of European governments, which have
opposed inclusion of forests in the CDM in the first commitment period
(2008-2012), the exclusion of the forests would force the USA to meet its Kyoto
commitments almost exclusively from domestic measures, most importantly an
increase in the price of gasoline; this would improve Europe’s industrial
competitiveness with the United States. This is due to the fact that the
emission quota for each industrialized country during the first commitment
period was fixed in the Kyoto conference in December 1997, in other words,
before reaching an agreement on the rules of the game, mainly on inclusion or
not of the tropical forests in the CDM. In the case of Brazil’s Ministry of
Foreign Relations, opposition to including avoided deforestation derives from
fear of threats to Brazil’s sovereignty in Amazonia, combined with a vision of
the process of deforestation as inherently beyond the government's control.
Other sections of Brazilian society, including the state governments in the
Amazon region, do not share the interpretation of the Ministry of Foreign
Relations. The best news with regard to the opposition of Brazilian diplomats
is the experience of deforestation control in Mato Grosso from 1999 to 2001,
indicating the government's capacity to control the process when it chooses to
do so (although there is still discrepancy with INPE data regarding 2001
deforestation in Mato Grosso).
For NGOs headquartered in Europe, opposition to
inclusion of forests follows logic parallel to that of the European
governments. It is best explained as a blow
against the United States, which is seen as deserving punishment for its many
sins in the world, including its place as the largest single emitter of
greenhouse gases and its role as an obstacle to international negotiations on
climate change. From the point of view of Brazilian NGOs interested in
maintaining the Amazon forest, these alternative agendas are side issues that,
although they may have merit, do not justify throwing away a major opportunity
for maintaining the forest. The technical arguments presented by critics of
avoided deforestation contain great distortions of the climatic consequences of
projects in this area. Proposals exist to deal with such issues as uncertainty
and the permanence of carbon; adoption of these would make the climatic
benefits of the avoided deforestation become a reality, allowing carbon
mitigation activities to provide a gain both for the climate and for
biodiversity and other values.
In July 2001 the Bonn agreement excluded avoided
deforestation from the CDM for the first commitment period, but the chances of
this type of mitigation entering in the CDM are much better for the second
period (2013-2017). This is because the
emission quotas of the industrial countries have not yet been negotiated, and
if forests are not included these countries will simply agree to decrease their
emissions by less. Decisions on the second period will be negotiated in
2005. In the same year the level for
“stabilization” of the concentration of CO2 in the atmosphere will
also be negotiated. The United Kingdom’s Hadley Centre has made catastrophic
forecasts concerning the survival of the Amazon forest from climate changes
that are expected without mitigation (Cox et
al., 2000, 2003); these simulations indicate that the stabilization level
should be below 550 parts per million by volume (ppmv) of CO2 to
avoid massive mortality of trees in the 21st century (Arnell et al., 2002). The future of the Amazon forest depends on
human decisions.
AMAZONIAN DEFORESTATION
On 25 June 2003, Brazil’s National
Institute for Space Research (INPE) released data on its website (Brazil, INPE,
2003) indicating two significant changes in Amazonian deforestation: a large
revision of the estimate for deforestation in 2001 (15% increase over the
preliminary 2001 estimate released in 2002), and a preliminary estimate for
deforestation in 2002 indicating a tremendous jump in the annual rate (40%
increase over the revised 2001 estimate).
Anecdotal evidence indicates that the rate for 2003 will also be
high. Among the disturbing features of
the 2002 data is an explosion of clearing activity around Novo Progresso, on
the BR-163 Highway. In the 185 × 185 km
LANDSAT scene (227-65) centered on Novo Progresso the deforestation rate more
than tripled in 2002 relative to the rate in 2001. This site has been the scene
of a frenetic migration of sawmills, ranchers and hopeful soybean planters in
anticipation of paving the highway under the 2004-2007 Pluriannual Plan, or
PPA—the successor to Avança Brasil (Fearnside, 2002a).
Most important is the meaning of
deforestation data for evaluating the success of the deforestation licensing
and control program in Mato Grosso. The
new results from INPE contain significant discrepancies with those from LANDSAT
imagery interpreted by the State Foundation for the Environment (FEMA) of the
Mato Grosso state government; these need to be clarified before firm
conclusions can be drawn (Fearnside and Barbosa, 2004). Data through 2000 offer several indications
that the control and licensing program was having an effect on clearing rates
(Fearnside, 2003). At the state level,
INPE data indicate the annual deforestation rate in Mato Grosso declining over
the 1999-2000 period while the rest of Amazonia had an upward trend in the same
period. However, the annual rate of
deforestation in Mato Grosso was already beginning to fall off before the control program began
in1999, indicating that at least part of the decline was probably the result of
running out of forest in some parts of the state. The decline in deforestation was sharper
after 1999, which is consistent with an effect from the program. In order to separate the effect of dwindling
forest from the enforcement program, FEMA data were examined from a series of
counties (municípios) with a range of
levels of previous clearing and with different dominant land uses: soybeans,
ranching, and small-farmer settlement (mixed with ranching), as well as
locations where enforcement effort was concentrated and not. The FEMA data used in these comparisons is
for clearing in all vegetation types, including cerrado, as well as forest, “transition” (note, this differs from
INPE data, which do not include clearing in cerrado). For counties with little previous clearing,
the FEMA data show the clearing rate increasing until 1999, after which the
trend reverses direction and declines; in contrast, in areas with clearing was
already well advanced, the annual rate declines beginning before 1999 and is
unaffected by the control program. This
pattern suggests that some of the decline at the state level is a result of the
program. Also consistent with this is a
stronger effect where the enforcement was concentrated.
County-level data for 2002 from FEMA
indicate a generalized upsurge in deforestation throughout Mato Grosso,
independent of the dominant land use, the degree of previous clearing, and the
level of enforcement. This may be a
reflection of anticipation among large landholders that Blairo Maggi would be
elected governor in the October 2002 elections, and that all previous
deforestation sins would be forgiven.
Maggi is the World’s largest individual soybean entrepreneur, and easily
won the 2002 election with a self-financed campaign (Edward, 2003). The effort and sophistication of the
enforcement program increased progressively since its inception in 1999, making
the upsurge in 2002 a disappointment. In
2002, enforcement increased substantially, with fines applied to 94% of the
area detected of illegal clearings larger than 200 ha (clearings subject to
control by FEMA). However, this finding
would have little effect in 2002 itself, since the clearing was almost always
already completed by the time of the inspection.
With the entry of the Maggi
administration in 2003, the enforcement program went into an obvious decline
(although it has not been officially abolished). Among the changes was disappearance of the
website where, beginning in 2001, public access had been provided to the list
of registered properties, with indications of what properties were in violation
of environmental legislation. The site
provided maps and measurements of clearings in legal reserves and permanently
protected areas in each property, together with the names, addresses and
identity information of the property owners.
The significance of the Mato Grosso
program for climate mitigation is considerable.
As an illustration, if one uses the clearing rate in 1999 as the
baseline (i.e., taking credit for all
reduction in the rate below the 1999 level), the average annual reduction in
clearing through 2000 was 319,393 ha, of which 223,559 ha was in forest and
transition. Considering the biomass of
each vegetation type and soil changes to 1-m depth, this reduction avoided an
emission of 36 million tonnes of carbon annually (Fearnside and Barbosa,
2003). An idea of the potential economic
significance can be gained by considering a carbon value of US$20/tonne (a
value used in budget planning by the Clinton administration in the US, which is
now purely illustrative due to the US withdrawal from the Kyoto negotiations in
March 2001 under the Bush administration and the exclusion of avoided
deforestation for the 2008-2012 period under the July 2001 Bonn Agreement).
What the price will actually be (i.e.,
what the supply and demand will be for CDM carbon credits) and what percentage
of avoided deforestation carbon can be claimed as credit will, of course,
depend on future decisions. At
US$20/tonne, the program would be producing a carbon value of US$722 million
annually. This would represent a maximum value, as it assumes that all carbon
is credited in full, without the adjustments for such factors as permanence,
uncertainty and leakage that are advocated by this author (e.g., Fearnside, 2001a).
Note that for the first commitment period, with no US participation and
with avoided deforestation excluded by the Bonn Agreement, the price of carbon
is expected to be only US$9/tonne C (den Elzen and de Moor, 2001).
If avoided deforestation is
eventually included in the CDM the bulk of the profit from sale of carbon
credit generated will go to project developers.
These might be federal agencies (such as the National Institute for the
Environment and Renewable Natural Resources-IBAMA), state governments, private
landowners, or cooperatives and citizens’ groups. A 5% tax on the proceeds will go to the
climate convention’s adaptation fund and for activities related to biodiversity
conservation); some of this smaller stream of funding may also become available
to Brazilian government and non-government organizations. The prospects for the use of funding
generated by avoided deforestation during the second commitment period will
depend heavily on experience gained with the more modest amounts of money
expected from the CDM during the first commitment period, when only projects
for plantations and energy-sector mitigation will be eligible credit. The difficulties in actually spending the
money properly to promote sustainable development and conservation are
tremendous (see discussion in Fearnside, 1997a). The great effort that has been needed to
spend smaller sums under the Pilot Program to Conserve the Brazilian Rainforest
(PPG7) makes this clear. Despite these
difficulties, the source of value must be maintained of the transition to an
economy based on environmental services is ever to take place. This means both recognition of the value of
avoiding deforestation and having a forest left to maintain.
GREENHOUSE-GAS EMISSIONS FROM DEFORESTATION
Amazonian deforestation makes a
significant contribution to global warming, but the amount of this contribution
has been the subject of extended controversies and strong political
implications underlie the debate. Half
of the dry weight of wood is carbon.
Both burning and decay release this carbon as greenhouse gases such as
carbon dioxide (CO2) and methane (CH4), in addition to
releasing non-carbon greenhouse gases such as nitrous oxide (N2O). The magnitude of greenhouse gas emissions
from deforestation in Brazil’s Amazon forest is the subject of longstanding
debate both inside and outside of Brazil.
The range of estimates is very large (e.g., R.J.A. Houghton et al., 2001). Only a relatively small part of this range is
the result of genuine differences in data for forest biomass and other relevant
factors. Most is from the choice of what
items to include in the estimates. The
choices made have direct impact on policy questions about which opinions are
sharply divided for non-scientific reasons.
Close examination of the effect of choices is therefore necessary. The goal should be to base all policies on
complete accounting.
The Brazilian government has long
had a pattern of announcing lower deforestation and emissions estimates than
what other evidence suggests (see Fearnside, 1997b, 2000a). Just before the Kyoto conference the
government even announced that the country produces zero net emissions from Amazonian deforestation [!] (IstoÉ, 1997). In recent years the official deforestation
rate estimates have been free of the errors understating deforestation that
occurred in several earlier estimates, but the calculations of emissions
continue to minimize the impact of deforestation on global warming.
The political context in Brazil was
made most explicit by José Domingos Gonzalez Miguez, head of the climate sector of the
Ministry of Science and Technology (MCT), in the transcript of a workshop on
the greenhouse gas emissions from reservoirs held at MCT’s Center for the
Management of Strategic Studies in Brasília in February 2002. Although this “smoking gun” relates to the
question of emissions by hydroelectric dams (see Fearnside, 2002b) rather than
deforestation for ranching and agriculture, the political context is the same:
“I asked for the help of
ELETROBRÁS [on the subject of
greenhouse gas emissions from dams];
actually, it was ELETROBRÁS that coordinated this work exactly because of this,
because this subject was becoming political.
It has a very great impact at the World level; we are going to suffer
pressure from the developed countries because of this subject. And, this subject was little known. It is mistreated. It is mistreated and continues to be
mistreated by Philip Fearnside himself, and we have to be very careful. The debate that is taking place now in the
press shows this clearly; that is to say, you can take any one-sided statement
to show that Brazil is not clean, that Brazil is very remiss, that Brazil,
implicitly, will have to take on a commitment [to reduce emissions] in the future. This is a great political debate and we are
preparing ourselves for it.” (Brazil, MCT, 2002).
It is worth noting
that the above confession is maintained on a public website administered by the
MCT climate sector itself. Needless to
say, the idea that research on emissions must be carefully “coordinated” in
order to assure that only politically palatable conclusions are reached is not
the only viewpoint. As unpopular as it
may be, I defend the position that all
sources and sinks of greenhouse gases must be quantified and taken into account
in policy making.
Brazil is preparing its first
national inventory of greenhouse gas emissions, as required the 1992 United
Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UN-FCCC) (UN-FCCC, 1992). The inventory is now several years late, but
is expected to be completed in 2004. The
current Brazilian inventory covers the 1988-1994 period, when the average
annual deforestation rate in Amazonia was 15.2 thousand km2. Estimates for the deforestation portion of
the report have evolved over time. In
August 2002, a preliminary estimate for this component totaled 90 million t C,
a value which was increased to 117 million t C in September 2003, but may
undergo further revision. My estimates
for the same period are 56% higher (Table 1).
Differences include counting below-ground biomass, dead trees, and trace
gases. The upsurge in the deforestation
rate in 2002 implies astronomical emissions—in the neighborhood of 450 million
tonnes of carbon annually (Table 1).
[Table1 here]
Controversies over numbers for
emissions from Amazonian deforestation are also common within the academic
community. A recent estimate by
researchers at the European Union’s Joint Research Centre, in Ispra, Italy, concluded
that emissions are much lower than what others have found (Achard et al., 2002; Eva et al., 2003). However, a
series of omissions in this low estimate adds up to an understatement of the global-warming
impact of deforestation by more than a factor of two (Fearnside and Laurance,
2003, 2004). Outside observers often
react to differing results among scientific groups by assuming that the truth
must lie somewhere between the two extremes, presumably at the midpoint.
Unfortunately, this kind of shortcut methodology is utterly insufficient: there
is no substitute for reading the original literature on these controversies and
tracing the origin of each item back to its source. Entering into this literature will quickly
reveal that many of the published estimates are little more than guesses. The reliability of an estimate depends on
three basic factors: the quality of the data, the quantity (and representativeness)
of the data, and the consistency of the interpretation.
Some values for input parameters in
emissions calculations are much better than others in terms of the underlying
data and in terms of the interpretation of those data. Great care must be taken that all components
of the carbon stock are included. Values
for the percentage of above-ground live biomass (AGLB) for frequently omitted
components include: trees less than 10 cm in diameter (12%), vines (4.3%),
palms (3.5%) and strangler figs and other “non-tree” components (0.2%) (Fearnside,
1994, 1997c, 2000c). A valid estimate
must include below-ground biomass, which averages 19.3% expressed as a
percentage of AGLB for all Amazonian forests (Fearnside et al., 1993) and dead biomass (necromass), which is typically
9-12% of AGLB (Nascimento and Laurance, 2002). The full emission must include
either the “committed emissions” after the year or (or multi-year time period)
used for the estimate, or the “inherited emissions” from decay or combustion of
biomass that remains unoxidized from deforestation in the years prior to the
year or period of interest. Regrowth in
the deforested landscape is often overestimated by using data on secondary
forests that are not derived from cattle pasture, which overwhelmingly
predominates as a land-use history and which produces secondary vegetation that
grows only slowly (Fearnside, 1996a; Fearnside and Guimarães, 1996). Soil carbon release from the top meter of
soil (9.6% of the impact: Fearnside, 2000c; Fearnside and Barbosa, 1998) is
often an additional omission. To fully
reflect the global-warming impact of deforestation, emissions of trace gases
such as CH4 and N2O must be included, as well as carbon (i.e., CO2). Inclusion of trace gases increases the impact
of deforestation by 15.5±9.5% over calculations that only consider carbon
(Fearnside, 2000b, pp. 143-145). All of
the above factors are omitted in varying degrees from a number of widely-used
emissions estimates for Amazonian deforestation (see Fearnside and Laurance,
2003).
TROPICAL DEFORESTATION IN THE KYOTO PROTOCOL
International negotiations on
climate change have been underway since the preparatory conferences for the
1992 “Earth Summit” (UNCED or ECO-92) in Rio de Janeiro. Tropical deforestation was considered a major
contributor to global warming by European governments and by
European-headquartered NGOs. A 1989
report published by Friends of the Earth-UK (Myers, 1989, p. 73) and a 1990
report published by Greenpeace (Leggett, 1990, p. 399), made similar
claims. This widespread agreement on the
importance of tropical deforestation would evaporate abruptly with the Kyoto
Protocol in December 1997, after which European governments and European-based
NGOs would turn against avoiding tropical deforestation as a form of mitigation.
The Kyoto Protocol established an
“assigned amount”, or quota, for the emissions of each of the countries in
Annex I of the Climate Convention and Annex B of the Kyoto Protocol (UN-FCCC,
1997). These are currently the developed
countries. The amount that each of these
countries could emit without penalty in the Kyoto Protocol’s first commitment
period (2008-2012) was fixed in Kyoto—but the rules of the game had not yet
been settled. Especially important was
the question of whether tropical forests would be included for credit under the
Protocol’s Clean Development Mechanism.
Blocks of countries formed with distinct positions on credit for
different types of forest-sector projects in the CDM (Table 2).
[Table 2 here]
GOVERNMENT
POSITIONS
BRAZIL
The Brazilian Ministry of Foreign
Relations (MRE) has opposed inclusion of avoided deforestation in the Clean
Development Mechanism, but at the same time has supported credit for
silvicultural plantations (i.e.,
afforestation and reforestation). This
split position makes Brazil unusual. It
should be emphasized that the official position of the portions of government
responsible for the negotiation (the Ministry of Foreign Relations and the
Minister of Science and Technology) differed sharply from that of other parts
of the government, such as the Ministry of the Environment. It is also relevant that the Minister of
Science and Technology during the presidential administration of Fernando
Henrique Cardoso (1995-2002) was a high-ranking diplomat from the Ministry of
Foreign Relations.
In June 1999, the divergent opinion
of the Ministry of the Environment became a matter of public record. At the meeting of environment ministers of
Amazonian countries, held in Cochabamba, Bolivia, the Brazilian minister of the
environment (José Sarney Filho) signed a joint declaration calling for approval
of credit under the CDM for avoided deforestation (Environment Ministers of the
Amazonian Countries, 1999). Sarney Filho
signed the document despite objections from the envoy from the Ministry of
Foreign Relations; the disagreement even took on the form of a physical
struggle, with Sarney Filho and the MRE representative engaged in a tug-of-war
for microphone, to the amazement of the audience (Luis Castello, personal
communication, 2000). Sarney Filho, who
was physically much more imposing than the slender young man who represented
MRE, easily won the contest. However, by
the time of the next meeting of the environment ministers, held in Quito,
Ecuador in October 1999, the Ministry of the Environment had been forbidden to
say anything related to the Kyoto negotiations.
It should be emphasized that
Brazilian negotiating policy for Kyoto has been set by a handful of
individuals, and the result is very much tied to the opinions of these
individuals, rather than to a logical argument on which there is wide
agreement. Each new set of individuals
represents a toss of the coin, and the probability is significant that key positions
will eventually be occupied by individuals who favor forests.
A sort of allergy has developed to
discussion of the role of avoiding tropical deforestation as a means of
mitigating climate change stems from fear of “international covetousness” – the
belief that the World at large is engaged in a permanent conspiracy to take
Amazonia away from Brazil. The key
individuals who determine Brazil’s negotiating stance all believe piously in
the threat internationalization, and fear that carbon could lead to
international interference with Brazilian sovereignty in Amazonia is at the
root of the aversion of the Ministry of Foreign affairs and the Minister of
Science and Technology to credit for avoided deforestation. Important as the internationalization theory
is in this arena (Council on Foreign Relations Independent Task Force, 2001,
Fearnside, 2001b), it is not, in itself, enough to explain the aversion to
carbon credit for avoided deforestation.
This is best illustrated by the case of the Governors of the Amazonian
states, who have traditionally been on the other side of the issue. These include Amazonino Mendes, governor of
Amazonas until 2002; in his political discourse, Amazonino Mendes constantly
raises the threat of international covetousness, yet he has been voluble in
support of carbon credit and even traveled to Chicago to try to sell Amazonian
forest carbon on international commodities markets.
The essential question is whether or
not one believes that Amazonian deforestation is controllable. The key individuals in Brazil’s negotiating
position believe that deforestation is inherently uncontrollable. If this is accepted as a starting point, then
if Brazil were to commit itself to reduce deforestation and then not actually
do so, the country could be open to international pressures. Although Article 12 (paragraph 5a) of the
Kyoto Protocol makes clear that the CDM is entirely voluntary, the fear
persists that Brazil could be threatened with economic punishments such as
tariffs on Brazilian exports ranging from orange juice to shoes unless the
country agrees accept carbon projects that are in the interest of major
economic powers, especially the United States.
If the impediment to using forest
conservation as a global-warming mitigation measure is concern over national
sovereignty, then it is national sovereignty that must be discussed and
examined, rather than debating the sources of climate change or the moral value
of changes in this century versus the next.
Admitting that sovereignty is the issue implies the need to subject this
problem to the same level of critical scrutiny as that applied to the technical
aspects of mitigation proposals. The
notion that the World is permanently conspiring to take Amazonia away from
Brazil is not likely to stand up to such scrutiny. Nevertheless, it is important to remember
that no amount of evidence is likely to change the opinion of the individual
diplomats involved, since the internationalization theory rests directly on
their “pre-analytical vision” (sensu
Daly and Cobb, 1989). Even the most
intelligent people only draw conclusions from the experiences that their
prejudices allow.
While the internationalization
theory is directly analogous to religion in terms of its means of acquisition
of belief, its immunity to “reason” and the need for respecting a diversity of
opinions, it is also analogous in another way.
This is in the proper relationship with government decision-making. With the exception of a few countries under
Islamic law, most present-day governments operate on the principle that church
and state should be separate. The same
principle should be applied to the internationalization creed.
REST
OF LATIN AMERICA
The Latin-American countries most active in the
effort to get rules approved for the CDM to allow credit for avoided
deforestation under the CDM were Bolivia, Costa Rica, Colombia and Mexico. Besides Brazil, only Peru (under President
Alberto Fujimori) opposed granting credit for avoided deforestation. Peru has since reversed its position
(Ambassador Armando Lecaros-de-Cossío, public statement, 31 October 2002). The question arises as to why the Fujimori
government in Peru opposed credit for forests in the Kyoto negotiations, a
stance that appears to be contrary to Peru’s national interest as a country
with substantial areas of tropical forest that could potentially generate
revenues through avoided deforestation projects under the CDM. The timing of Peru’s adoption of this
position is intriguing: Peru’s opposition was made known at the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) plenary session in Montreal in
February 2000--just weeks before the 9 April first round of Fujimori’s
“re-re-election”. Peru’s opposition to
avoided deforestation represented a reversal of its previous position (e.g., Environment Ministers of the
Amazonian Countries, 1999). During the
“crisis” between the allegedly fraudulent 9 April first round and the 28 May
runoff election, Brazil showed support for Fujimori by granting Order of the
Southern Cross medals to three of Fujimori’s cabinet ministers and, perhaps
more importantly, by receiving a secret delegation of Peruvian diplomats and
informally agreeing to support the official results of the upcoming runoff
election even if the validity of the election were to be questioned by the
international community (Folha de São
Paulo, 2000). The runoff election,
in which Fujimori ran unopposed, was questioned by the Organization of American
States (OEA), but Brazil was decisive in blocking sanctions against Peru by the
OEA (Cantanhêde, 2000). The tilt towards
Fujimori was unexpected in light of Brazil’s customary discourse in favor of
democratic institutions. Fujimori was
eventually forced from office in November 2000, by which time Brazil had
discretely ceased to support him.
Conclusions about whether there was a causal link between the Fujimori
government’s positions on Kyoto and Brazil’s suggestively timed support in the
first half of 2000 will necessarily remain speculative until such time as the
diplomatic records of Brazil and/or Peru are released to the academic
community.
CHINA AND INDIA
China and India are key countries in
discussions regarding global warming because these countries are likely to
greatly increase their emissions in the coming decades, as a result both of
population growth and increased consumption.
These countries have little forest left to deforest and have tremendous
emissions from inefficient fossil fuel combustion. China and India therefore see allowing
inexpensive credit from avoided deforestation as competition that would reduce
their chance to profit from energy-related CDM projects (Dutschke, 2002, p.
385). It is worth noting that Brazilian
diplomats have cultivated China and India as potential allies in climate
negotiations.
USA
The United States is the World’s largest single
emitter of greenhouse gases, with a baseline emission of 1.6 billion tonnes of
carbon in 1990 from fossil fuel and cement.
Prior to the Kyoto conference, the US Senate approved a motion by a vote of
95 to zero advising the President that no agreement would be ratified
unless it included a significant commitment by developing countries to reduce
emissions. In the weeks before the Kyoto
conference, and during the three months leading up to the conference, the
fossil fuel industry spent US$13 million in advertising in the US to convince
the public that global warming is scientifically unfounded (Beder, 1999). Public understanding of the problem is still
low in the US, a feature that extends to the country’s current president
(George W. Bush), who has made a variety of statements indicating his
skepticism about climate science. On 13
March 2001, only two months after taking office and before he had appointed any
science advisors, Bush withdrew the US from Kyoto negotiations over the first
commitment period. The US has not
withdrawn is participation in the 1992 Climate Convention, and continues to
send representatives to negotiating meetings.
During the period when the US was
engaged in the Kyoto negotiations, the country supported granting credit for
avoided deforestation, as did other members of the “Umbrella Group” such as
Canada, Japan and New Zealand. It should
be emphasized that this position cannot be interpreted as a sign of
environmental concern, but rather as a means of minimizing the cost of
compliance with the Kyoto agreement. It
could, nevertheless, be used to environmental advantage to obtain resources for
maintaining tropical forests.
EUROPE
In 1989 Germany held a series of
parliamentary hearings on tropical deforestation and climate change (in two of
which this author testified), and the resulting report identified reducing
deforestation as a top priority to avoid global warming (Deutscher Bundestag,
1990). The Pilot Programme to Conserve
the Brazilian Rainforest (PPG7) was negotiated in the lead-up to the 1992
United Nations Convention on Environment and Development (UNCED, or ECO-92) in
Rio de Janeiro. This author served for
nine years (1993-2001) as a member of the Programme’s International Advisory
Group, during which time the G7 countries (primarily European countries)
contributed over US$250 million to the Programme. Among the objectives of the PPG7 was to
reduce the emission of carbon dioxide from tropical deforestation (World Bank,
1992). In fact, of the four supposedly
equal objectives of the program, this was undoubtedly the “most equal” from the
point of view of the PPG7’s European donor countries at that time. Germany was and remains the largest funder of
the PPG7. Needless to say, this echoes
from a previous age, given that the European countries, especially Germany,
suddenly turned against forests as evil “sinks” in the Kyoto negotiations from
December 1997 until the Bonn Agreement in July 2001.
In the negotiations following from Kyoto the theoretical argument these
European countries against assigning any value to avoided deforestation is
based on the notion that only the very long term (i.e. equilibrium) composition of the atmosphere matters and that
combating tropical deforestation is therefore unimportant because forests are
likely to be cut and/or burned anyway for one reason or another over the course
of a few centuries. Obviously, in the
context of the PP-G7 the European countries think that avoided deforestation
has a real value for climate, even though the impossibility of controlling
history over a time scale of centuries means that the carbon in the forests
might eventually be emitted to the atmosphere.
The European counties were not wrong in 1991, nor in the years since
then over which they have supported this ongoing program. Instead, they are being hypocritical now in
claiming that emissions avoidance only has value if it is permanent and
certain.
The geographical distribution of
national positions on the issue of crediting avoided deforestation could not be
more striking, with opposition concentrated in Europe, and North America
favoring credit. The parameter that
matches this distribution most perfectly is that of gasoline prices (Table
3). In virtually any European country a
liter of gasoline costs at least double the price in the USA (Sheehan, 2001, p.
48).
[Table 3 here]
NGO
POSITIONS
NGO positions on the Clean
Development Mechanism are listed in Table 4.
Some obvious patterns emerge. Brazilian grassroots NGOs universally support credit for avoided
deforestation, including groups throughout Brazil’s Amazon region. These include the National Council of
Rubbertappers (CNS) (founded by Chico Mendes and his allies), the largest
organization of indigenous peoples in the region (COIAB), and groups
representing hundreds of small-farmer organizations (GTA, FETAGRI and CPT)
(“Manifestação ...”, 2000). Brazilian
research NGOs, such as ISA, IPAM and IMAZON, have a similar position, although
there is one exception (Vitae Civilis) (“A Brazilian NGO Declaration”,
2000). Brazilian branches and affiliates
of European-headquartered “international” NGOs, such as WWF, Greenpeace and
FOE-Porto Alegre, have opposed credit for forests in line with their European
headquarters; an important exception has been FOE-Brazilian Amazonia, which has
resisted pressure from Europe and assumed a leading role in promoting credit
for forest carbon (e.g., Monzoni et al.,
2000). The pattern in the United
States is exactly parallel to that in Brazil, with US-headquartered NGOs (EDF,
TNC, NRDC, and UCS) supporting credit for forests and US branches and
affiliates of European-based NGOs, such as WWF, Greenpeace and FOE, opposing
it.
[Table 4
here]
The positions of the European NGOs
underwent an abrupt turnabout at the time of the December 1997 Kyoto
Protocol. Prior to that time, the same
NGOs had argued strongly in favor of using forests as a tool to combat global warming,
for example in a 1989 report by Friends of the Earth-UK (Myers, 1989), and in
the 1990 Greenpeace report on global warming:
“It now appears that one of the most cost-effective and technically
feasible ways to counter the greenhouse effect lies with grand-scale
reforestation in the tropics as a means to sequester carbon dioxide from the
global atmosphere—provided, of course, that the strategy is accompanied by
greatly increased efforts to slow deforestation.” (Myers, 1990, p. 399).
Such statements would
be considered absolute heresy by Greenpeace and other European NGOs after
1997. Carbon sequestration through
reforestation (i.e. plantations)
became anathema to these NGOs, and, unfortunately for tropical forests, these
NGOs chose to lump avoided emissions through forest conservation under the same
catchword as “sinks”.
The reasoning, as described in the various publications and websites of
these organizations, is well represented by the following quotation from WWF:
“every ton of carbon absorbed by a sink allows a ton of carbon to be
emitted from burning fossil fuels” (WWF Climate Action Campaign, 2000).
Taking such statements
at face value for the moment, it is important to recognize that this
interpretation of the Kyoto Protocol is in error. It is not every tonne of carbon “absorbed”
but every tonne of credit that is granted that permits a tonne of fossil fuel
carbon to be emitted. The credit is very
different from the physical tonne of carbon present in the trees. Credit is a piece of paper that will be
negotiated on international commodity exchanges. Nothing in the Kyoto Protocol specifies a
one-to-one ratio between the physical carbon and the credit; one could easily
grant substantially less credit for each tonne of physical carbon in order to
more than compensate for concerns regarding permanence of carbon, leakage
(indirect effects outside of the project boundaries that nullify the climatic
benefit) and uncertainty. Throwing out
the forest option is foolhardy for various reasons, including the obvious fact
that the task of combating global warming so greatly exceeds the capacity of
different individual mitigation measures that one must use all available
measures to confront the problem.
The European NGOs seized upon the
question of permanence as a defect of forests and dismissed forest carbon as a
“loophole” or a “dangerous distraction” (e.g.,
Greenpeace, 2000; WWF Climate Action Campaign, 2000). Permanence is falsely portrayed as an
all-or-nothing proposition: either carbon is permanent or it is worthless by
this view. Greenpeace drafted a document
explaining how a tonne of carbon might be sequestered by a forest project for
100 years, after which the carbon is released when the forest burns down or is
otherwise destroyed (Meinshausen and Hare, 2000). The atmosphere thereby winds up with two
tonnes of emitted carbon: one from fossil fuels that were permitted to be
emitted by the carbon credit, and the other from the trees destroyed at the end
of 100 years. The argument has two problems: the assumption of a one-to-one
ratio between carbon credit and physical carbon in the forestry project, and
the assumption that holding a tonne of carbon out of the atmosphere for 100
years has no value to human society. In
fact, holding carbon out of the atmosphere for finite periods has substantial
value in that a corresponding quantity of impacts (including human deaths)
would be averted over the period that the carbon remains out of the atmosphere
(Fearnside, 2002c).
Greenpeace lawyers stress two
clauses to bolster their rejection of carbon that is less-than-permanent. One is Article 2 of the UN Framework
Convention on Climate Change (UN-FCCC), which defines the purpose of the
Convention in terms of “stabilization” of atmospheric concentrations of
greenhouse gases. Because emissions
changes require on the order of 200 years to be reflected in a new equilibrium
of atmospheric gases, the transient course of our pathway to reaching
stabilization would have no importance under the UN-FCCC. Unfortunately, this grossly misrepresents the
interests of human society, which will be greatly affected by climate changes
over the coming decades and not only by the situation 200 or more years in the
future. The other legal argument used is
that Article 12 of the Kyoto Protocol, which creates the Clean Development
Mechanism, specifies that the benefits must be “long term”—leaving the question
of what constitutes “long term” up to future negotiations. Greenpeace has even gone so far as to demand
that carbon be held for “geological time”.
Luis Gylvan Meira Filho, one of the most influential voices shaping the
Brazilian negotiating position, has argued for considering events as long as
35,000 years in the future (see Fearnside, 2002d). Needless to say, these positions would render
any kind of forest project unviable.
The intellectual argument for
dismissing forests as an option based on infinite or very long time horizons
runs counter to the interests of human society and the way that decisions are
made in virtually all other spheres. The
21st Century must not be dismissed as unimportant in order to try
for presumed climatic gains several centuries or millenia in the future. Projections of global warming over the course
of the 21st Century imply catastrophic changes in this time frame
(J.T. Houghton et al., 2001). This
century will be critical both for the climate and for the fate of Brazil’s
Amazon forest.
As indicated earlier, there are
strong reasons not to believe that
the intellectual arguments regarding such issues as permanence represent the
real reason for the positions adopted by the European NGOs. The geographical distribution of the
positions of the different groups and governments makes the probability of this
explanation being correct vanishingly small.
People in Europe are not more concerned with distant generations than
are people in South America, Central America or North America. Basically, the intellectual structure that
the European NGOs have erected is best viewed as a smokescreen of sophistry
that has been built for the purpose of justifying a position that is based on a
hidden agenda. Most rank-and-file
members of European NGOs would probably be hard pressed to explain the
intellectual rationale of their opposition to avoided deforestation, but simply
accept without question that all “sinks” must be bad if WWF, Greenpeace and
Friends of the Earth say so.
The underlying motivation of the
European NGOs is parallel, but not identical, to that of the European
governments. Unlike the governments,
NGOs are not much concerned with economic competitiveness and terms of trade,
but the opportunity to strike a blow at United States drew the governments and
the NGOs together in a common position.
NGO members, as with much of the European population, dislike the US for
a variety of reasons (see Fearnside, 2001c).
In the area of climate, the US is, in fact, the principal villain, being
the largest single emitter of greenhouse gasses on the Planet and having repeatedly
maneuvered to block or weaken international efforts to contain global
warming. The March 2001 decision by US
President George W. Bush to withdraw from negotiations for the first commitment
period of the Kyoto Protocol was only the crowning incident in a long series of
diplomatic efforts to weaken international agreements on climate change, dating
from the preparatory meetings leading up to the 1992 UNCED (ECO-92) meeting
that approved the UN-FCCC (e.g.,
Carvalho, 1992). Punishing the US is the
primary reason for opposing credit for forests in the CDM.
It is difficult to converse with
European NGO campaigners for more than a few seconds on the subject of credit
for forest carbon without hearing the opinion that that we “can’t let the US
off for cheap”. Two considerations are
relevant. First, the cost of the
mitigation is irrelevant to climate change, as a tonne of carbon emission
avoided has the same effect, whether it was achieved by cheap or expensive
means. In fact, low cost is beneficial
for climate change in that it encourages willingness to make deeper cuts in
emissions in future commitment periods.
Second, nobody is suggesting that the US or any other country should be
“let off” and allowed not to meet the commitments agreed to in Kyoto. By appropriate assignment of credit, allowing
projects for avoided deforestation would fully meet (and, in reality, exceed)
the emissions reductions promised in Kyoto.
The debate over the role of tropical
forests in mitigating global warming has revealed in unprecedented clarity the
undemocratic nature of many “international” NGOs. These organizations function well when all
are in basic agreement, for example for issues like saving whales. This changes dramatically when issues divide
along geographical lines, as in the question of forests in the CDM. While NGO branches are allowed to have some
differences of opinion on minor issues, on “key issues” all branches and
employees are expected to close ranks around a single position. The question of forests in the CDM has been
considered to be such a “key issue.” The
positions adopted on key issues are virtually always those of the European
branches, which are more numerous than those from any other part of the world,
including North America. Employees of
Brazilian branches of European NGOs suffered a long series of subtle and
not-so-subtle pressures, with several notable casualties on the Brazilian side
(see Fearnside, 2001a).
European NGO reaction to the
existence of a different viewpoint in Brazil has been that the Brazilian NGOs
are under the influence of North-Americans because few European NGO staff speak
Portuguese and they lack a tradition of working in Brazil. Needless to say, the implication that Brazilian
NGOs have been tricked by NGOs from North America, and that they are mere pawns
in a game masterminded from the US, would not be well received in Brazil. Brazilian NGOs are fully capable of thinking
for themselves and arriving at their own conclusions. The other theory presented to explain the
difference is that Brazilian NGOs have favored credit for forests because they
want money from the carbon credits. The
prospect of monetary flows is, indeed, a reason for interest in carbon credits. However, this in no way can be construed as a
sin. The desire to use the environmental
services of the forest as a new basis for economic development in the region is
a healthy shift, and very much furthers the environmental objectives of the
NGOs.
It is very important to distinguish
between avoided deforestation and plantation silviculture, despite the two
being frequently lumped as “sinks” in European NGO discourse. They are very different, both in terms of
carbon benefits and in terms of their impacts and benefits for biodiversity and
social concerns (Fearnside, 1996b).
Avoided deforestation almost always is more beneficial.
It is important to realize that the
reasons for the different positions on forest carbon are not scientific, despite the debate frequently being couched in
scientific terms. The NGOs have a
scientific argument that, combined with moral choices regarding time horizon,
time preference and “ancillary” effects, leads to their conclusion of rejecting
avoided deforestation. However, an
equally sound scientific argument, combined with different moral choices on the
other critical factors, leads to the opposite conclusion.
It is also very important to
distinguish between what is a scientific conclusion and what is a moral
judgment. Science can provide answers to
questions such as “how much carbon will a given project hold out of the
atmosphere, for how long and with what degree of certainty”. It cannot tell us whether that answer means
that the CDM should include or exclude avoided deforestation. Such a conclusion requires moral
choices. We must have the courage to
admit that we are making moral decisions, and to go ahead and make them.
It would be consummate foolishness
to throw away the Amazon rainforest in exchange for a climate benefit several
centuries or millennia in the future.
Despite the discourse of European NGOs justifying their positions in
terms of the interests of generations in the [far] future, it would be well to
remember the famous words of E.O. Wilson that allowing the Earth’s wealth of
species to be lost is “the folly that our descendants are least likely to
forgive us” (Wilson, 1992).
The debate over forest carbon as a
mitigation option in terms of an arcane jargon regarding such concepts as
leakage, additionality, permanence and uncertainty leads many to be
confused. However, no one is confused
who is closer to the heat of the burning in Amazonia, as evinced by the
positions of Brazilian NGOs. One needs
to know what it looks, sounds, smells and feels like to be at the frontier
where trees are being chain-sawed and burned. It is difficult for those closer
to the burning to understand how any environmental organization could take a
stand that implies throwing away one of the most important opportunities for
maintaining tropical forests.
The forces driving deforestation in
Amazonia have evolved continuously over the past three decades. Today, powerful economic forces such as
soybeans are much greater threats than when a larger share of clearing and its
underlying infrastructure were driven by an economically weaker lobby of
ranchers and land speculators (Fearnside, 2001d). Substantial funds will be necessary to change
some of these trends. The hard fact is
that there is no other money on the table that is likely to fill this
role. The Convention on Biological
Diversity, for example, is well behind the UN-FCCC in terms of having billions
of dollars of potential funding in the coming years.
The common European NGO response
that tropical forests should be protected with money from other sources, such
as the Biodiversity Convention, is only a diversion, since significant amounts
of money simply do not exist in these “other” sources. None of the countries (or NGOs) suggesting
that these sources be used is offering to put billions of dollars on the
table. The same applies to calls for
using the Kyoto Protocol’s adaptation fund (Article 4.8) for saving tropical
forests. Needless to say, countries
where the human population will soon be facing heavy impacts from climate
change would not take kindly to having the scant adaptation resources provided
by the Protocol diverted to conservation projects elsewhere.
The funds potentially available
through climate mitigation could make a tremendous difference for tropical
forest conservation, in addition to generating real carbon benefits at highly
competitive cost. An illustration of
scale is offered by the expectations of State Department planners during the
Clinton administration in the US: over the 2008-2010 first commitment period a
gap of 600 million tonnes of carbon was expected annually above domestic
energy-sector mitigation results. If all
were purchased abroad through the various “flexibility mechanisms” in the Kyoto
Protocol, the total for the US would be US$12 billion/year at the US$20/tC
carbon price projected at that time. The
US wanted to obtain 300 million t C of credit from Articles 3.3 and 3.4
(domestic afforestation, reforestation and deforestation activities, plus
“other” activities such as forest and soil management), leaving a shortfall of
300 million t C for mechanisms like the CDM; this 300 million t C corresponds
to an expected cost of US$6 billion/year.
Prior to its withdrawal from Kyoto negotiations, the US represented
approximately half of the expected total demand for carbon credits.
NGOs that oppose using carbon funds
to maintain forests seem to have forgotten that some urgency is appropriate
with respect to combating biodiversity loss. If we wait until the second
commitment period begins in 2013, there won’t be nearly as much tropical forest
left to save. Not taking advantage of the carbon value of tropical forests in
the efforts to save them, claiming as an excuse that saving tropical forests is
an objective that is doomed to failure, is inappropriate as a stand for
environmental NGOs. It is no time to
throw in the towel on Brazil’s Amazonian deforestation when only 16% of the
forest has been cleared. Instead,
environmental NGOs should be committed to fighting deforestation tree by tree.
International NGOs should take stock
of what they are trying to accomplish.
Organizations like WWF represent their stakeholders, who are a
contributing membership composed of people who are primarily concerned about
biodiversity. In the 21st Century it is habitat loss, especially
tropical deforestation, which is likely to be the greatest threat to
biodiversity. On longer timescales
climate change would rise in importance, and in this case would act mainly in
finishing off species that had escaped a century of direct habitat
destruction. In keeping biodiversity and
carbon issues in perspective, it should be remembered that carbon is more
reversible than most environmental problems, such as biodiversity loss, toxic
and nuclear wastes, or ozone loss. This
is also true of underlying forces such as population growth and rising
per-capita consumption.
European NGOs take great pains to find weaknesses in avoided
deforestation projects (as well as with plantation projects). This “watchdogging” effort provides a
valuable service. On the other hand, the
same information on project defects can be used for two distinct purposes. One is to suggest improvements to the system
that will help to make the CDM work. The
other is to provide ammunition to efforts to torpedo the entire process. The first use is an appropriate goal of
environmental NGOs, while the second is counterproductive for both the climate
and biodiversity objectives of these organizations.
The process of developing carbon
mitigation projects is inherently difficult, with multiple opportunities for
some portion of the credit granted to be for activities that have less climatic
benefit in reality than they do in the official accounting (Fearnside, 1999a,
2003, 2004b; Van Vliet et al.,
2003). This applies both to energy and
forest sector projects (Herzog et al.,
2003). The important question here is
what should be done: should one work to solve or at least minimize the various
problems as they are identified, or should one simply oppose all credit a priori. I would argue that it is essential to have an
attitude of making it work.
In going forward, it is essential
that focus be maintained on the second commitment period (2013-2017). Negotiations for this period will begin in
2005, making the issues extremely current.
All environmental NGOs concerned with climate, including those based in
Europe, will have to reach out to grassroots NGOs if effective alliances are to
be built to maintain tropical forest.
The history of European NGOs having turned their back on over 500
grassroots groups in the Brazilian Amazon is an unfortunate backdrop, but it
must be overcome if the common goals of maintaining forests are to be achieved.
LIKELY
CHANGES
The Bonn and Marrakech accords of
2001 ruled out avoided deforestation for the first commitment period (2008-2012),
but the question remains open for the second and subsequent commitment
periods. The finalization of the
decisions on the first commitment period changes the underlying motivations for
the opposition that has existed to forests and opens the way for the various
groups to make peace with each other.
Another change has been European NGO
positions on temporary certified emissions reductions (T-CERs). This proposal (Blanco and Forner, 2000),
known as the “Colombian proposal”, was rejected prior to the July 2001 Bonn
agreement. The European Union (EU) also
rejected the proposal. After plantation silviculture was included in the CDM
under the Bonn agreement, T-CERs were seen by both the EU and the European NGOs
as the best way to do the carbon accounting.
Again, this is a healthy change.
However, one might wonder, if T-CERs are now seen as the best accounting
method for forestry projects, why weren’t they supported prior to inclusion of
forestry becoming a fait accompli? The obvious reason is that doing so would
have been an admission that the “permanence problem”, which was constantly
presented as an insurmountable obstacle to having meaningful climate benefits
from forestry, could indeed be solved.
The sudden switch in positions on T-CERs was essentially a confession of
hypocrisy indicating that before the Bonn agreement the European governments
and NGOs had simply been maneuvering to block all forest projects by thwarting
any efforts to solve the problems associated with them. Adoption of T-CERs effectively removes any
intellectual foundation for future opposition to avoided deforestation on the
basis of permanence—but intellectual consistency has clearly not always been a
priority in the past efforts of European NGOs to block inclusion of forests in
the CDM.
The good news in this arena is that
for the second commitment period there is no motive to keep forests out. The fact that the assigned amounts (emissions
quotas) will be renegotiated means that keeping forests out of the CDM would
only result in the various countries agreeing to reduce their national
emissions by more modest amounts than they would if forests are included for
credit.
ARTICLE
17: EMISSIONS TRADING
While the CDM, namely Article 12 of the Kyoto
Protocol, is the focus of the vast majority of debate regarding forests in the
Protocol, it should never be forgotten that this is not the only way that the
Protocol could provide carbon credit for maintaining tropical forests. Article 17 (Emissions Trading) also offers
this possibility to members of Annex I of the UN-FCCC and Annex B of the Kyoto
Protocol—those countries that have accepted caps on their national emissions
totals. Article 3.7 of the Protocol (the
“Australia clause”) specifies that any Annex B country that had a positive
emission of carbon from its forests in 1990 can trade any difference below the
baseline established in the initial national inventory through the “emissions
trading” provisions of Article 17. With
the exception of Australia, the current members of Annex B, such as the United
States, are thereby excluded from trading forest carbon based on their national
inventories, but Brazil, were it to join Annex I and Annex B, could trade this
carbon at will. This represents a
substantial opportunity for Brazil, and would suffer much less loss of credit
than would be the case for the project-based mitigation allowed under the CDM
(Fearnside, 1999b, 2001d). All emissions
reductions below the baseline can be traded, without need to show a causal link
to the results of any given mitigation project.
The major questions for this option relate to whether the Brazilian
government could, in fact, reduce deforestation rates to levels below those in
the period chosen as the baseline for the national inventory (1988-1994). The Brasil
em Ação (Brazil in Action) and Avança
Brasil (Forward Brazil) plans of the Fernando Henrique Cardoso government
have been succeeded by the Plano
Plurianual (Pluriannual Plan), or “PPA”, of the Luiz Inácio Lula da Silva
government, but the current plan is just as ambitious as its predecessors in
proposing extensive highway paving and other infrastructure projects that make
slowing deforestation more difficult.
Despite the great reversal represented by the upsurge in deforestation
in 2002 to 25.5 thousand km2 per year (versus 15.2 thousand km2
per year in the baseline period), the process could still be brought under
control if the government so decided (Fearnside, 2003; Fearnside and Barbosa,
2004).
CONCLUSIONS
Amazonian deforestation makes a
significant contribution to global warming.
Complete accounting of emissions and uptakes is needed to reflect the
climatic impact of deforestation and the consequent benefits of avoiding it. Gaining credit for avoided deforestation
could provide substantial potential environmental and economic benefit to
Brazil, particularly to Amazonia.
Changes in the way that Kyoto negotiations fit into the wider
geopolitical context greatly increase the chances of avoided deforestation
becoming eligible for credit under the Clean Development Mechanism (Kyoto
Protocol Article 12) in the second commitment period (2013-2017). Credit for avoided deforestation through
emissions trading (Kyoto Protocol Article 17) remains a possibility with
substantially greater potential gains, but is threatened by continued plans in
the Pluriannual Plan (PPA, the successor to Avança Brasil) for extensive
highway paving and other infrastructure projects that make slowing
deforestation more difficult. The most
positive sign is the experience with deforestation control in Mato Grosso over
the 1999-2001 period, providing a concrete example of the ability of the
government to prevent landholders from clearing if the government wishes to do
so. The substantial value of avoided
deforestation is the most likely source of the political will that is needed
for this to happen in a sustained fashion and on a large scale.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
An earlier version of this paper was
presented at the Third European Congress of Latin-Americanists (CEISAL) on
“Crossing frontiers in Latin America”, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 3-6 July
2002. The author’s work is supported by
the National Council for Scientific and Technological Development (CNPq)(Proc.
470765/01-1).
LITERATURE CITED
F. Achard, H.D. Eva, H.J. Stibig,
P. Mayaux, J. Gallego, T. Richards and J-P. Malingreau, ´Determination of
deforestation rates of the world’s humid tropical forests,´ Science, vol. 297(2002), pp. 999-1002.
N.W. Arnell, M.G.R. Cannell, M. Hulme, R.S.
Kovats, J.F.B. Mitchell, R.J. Nichols,
M.L. Parry, M.T.J. Livermore, A. White, ´The consequences of CO2
stabilisation for the impacts of climate change,´ Climatic Change, vol. 53(2002), pp. 413-446.
S. Beder. ‘Corporate hijacking of the
greenhouse debate,’ The Ecologist,
vol. 29, no, 2(1999), pp. 119-122.
J.T. Blanco and C. Forner, (2000), Expiring
CERs: A proposal to addressing the permanence issue for LUCF projects in the
CDM. Unpublished manuscript, Economic and Financial Analysis Group, Ministry of
the Environment, Bogotá, Colombia. 4 pp.
FCCC/SB/2000/MISC.4/Add.2/Rev.1, 14 September 2000. (available at
http//www.unfccc.de).
Brazil, INPE (Instituto Nacional de Pesquisas Espaciais), (2003), Taxas nos períodos 2000-2001 e 2001-2002 para 50 cenas críticas. http://www.obt.inpe.br/prodes/prodes_2002_2002.htm.
Brazil, MCT (Ministério da Ciência e Tecnologia), (2002), Degravação do
workshop: Utilização de Sistemas Automáticos de Monitoramento e Medição de
Emissões de Gases de Efeito Estufa da Qualidade da Água em Reservatórios de
Hidrelétricas. Centro de Gestão de Estudos Estratégicos do MCT, Brasília – DF,
06 de fevereiro de 2002. (Brasília, DF, Brazil: Ministério da Ciência e
Tecnologia (MCT)), http://www.mct.gov.br/clima/brasil/doc/workad.doc.
“A Brazilian NGO Declaration” (2000) A
Brazilian NGO declaration on forests and climate change within the scope of the
Clean Development Mechanism of the Kyoto Protocol, (Vitae Civilis: São Lourenço
da Serra, São Paulo, Brazil), 1 p.
E. Cantanhêde. “Brasil quer manifestar repúdio a Fujimori,” Folha de São Paulo, (29 July 2000), p. A12.
B. Carvalho. “Conferência Preparatória: EUA rejeitam acordo sobre CO2 e jogam mais ‘água fria’ na reunião,” Folha de São Paulo, (26 March 1992), p. 1-7.
Council on Foreign Relations Independent Task
Force (2001) A letter to the President and a memorandum on U.S. policy toward
Brazil. (New York, U.S.A.: Council on Foreign Relations), 13 pp. (available
from: http://www.cfr.org).
P.M.
Cox, R.A. Betts, M. Collins, P. Harris, C. Huntingford and C.D. Jones 2003.
Amazonian dieback under climate-carbon cycle projections for the 21st century.
Hadley Center Technical Note No. 42, (Wallingford, U.K.: Hadley Centre),
(http://www.meto.gov.uk/research/hadleycentre/pubs/HCTN/HCTN_42.pdf).
P.M. Cox, R.A. Betts, C.D. Jones,
S.A. Spall and I.J. Totterdell ´Acceleration of global warming due to
carbon-cycle feedbacks in a coupled climate model,´ Nature, vol. 408(2000), pp.184-187.
H.E. Daly and
J.B. Cobb, (1989). For the Common Good:
Redirecting the Economy toward Community, the Environment and a Sustainable
Future. (Boston, MA, U.S.A.: Beacon Press), 482 pp.
M.G.J. den Elzen and A.P.G. de Moor (2001). Evaluating the Bonn Agreement and some key
issues. RIVM Report No. 728001016/2001. (Bilthoven, the Netherlands:
National Institute of Public Health and the Environment-RIVM), 34 pp.
Deutscher Bundestag (1990) Protecting the Tropical Forests: A High-Priority International Task. Referat Öffentlichkeitsarbeit, (Bonn,
Germany: Deutscher Bundestag). 968 pp.
M. Dutschke, ´Fractions
of permanence – Squaring the cycle of sink carbon accounting,´ Mitigation
and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change, vol. 7(2002), pp. 381-402.
J. Edward, ´Mato Grosso: O trator no
governo´. Veja [São Paulo], (10
December 2003), pp. 84-86.
Environment Ministers of the Amazonian
Countries, (1999), ‘Meeting of the Ministers of
Environment and Forestry of the Amazonian Countries on Clean Development
Mechanism (CDM),’ held in Cochabamba, Bolivia, 14-15 June 1999. (translation by
World Bank, Brasília, DF, Brazil).
H.D. Eva, F. Achard, H-J. Stibig
and P. Mayaux, ´Response to comment on “Determination of deforestation rates of
the World’s humid tropical forests”,´ Science,
vol. 299(2003), p. 1015b.
P.M. Fearnside (1994) ´Biomassa das florestas Amazônicas
brasileiras´ Pages 95-124 in
Anais do seminário emissão × seqüestro de CO2. (Rio de Janeiro,
Brazil: Companhia Vale do Rio Doce-CVRD). 221 pp.
P.M.
Fearnside, ‘Amazonian deforestation and global warming: Carbon stocks in
vegetation replacing Brazil's Amazon forest,’ Forest Ecology and Management, vol. 80, nos. 1-3(1996a), pp. 21-34.
P.M. Fearnside
(1996b). ‘Socio-economic factors in the management of tropical forests for
carbon’ Pages 349-361. in M.J. Apps
and D.T. Price (eds.) Forest Ecosystems,
Forest Management and the Global Carbon Cycle. (Heidelberg, Germany:
Springer-Verlag), 452 pp.
P.M.
Fearnside, ‘Environmental services as a strategy for sustainable development in
rural Amazonia,’ Ecological Economics, vol. 20, no. 1(1997a), pp. 53-70.
P.M.
Fearnside, ‘Monitoring needs to transform Amazonian forest maintenance into a
global warming mitigation option,’ Mitigation
and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change, vol. 2, nos. 2-3(1997b), pp.
285-302.
P. M. Fearnside,
‘Greenhouse gases from deforestation in Brazilian Amazonia: Net committed
emissions,’ Climatic Change, vol. 35,
no. 3(1997c), pp. 321-360.
P.M.
Fearnside, ‘Forests and global warming mitigation in Brazil: Opportunities in
the Brazilian forest sector for responses to global warming under the
"Clean Development Mechanism",’ Biomass
and Bioenergy, vol. 16, no. 3(1999a), pp. 171-189.
P.M. Fearnside, ‘Como o efeito estufa pode render dinheiro para o Brasil,’ Ciência Hoje vol. 26, no. 155(1999b), pp. 41-43.
P.M. Fearnside, ‘Effects
of land use and forest management on the carbon cycle in the Brazilian Amazon,’
Journal of Sustainable Forestry, vol.
12, nos. 1-2(2000a), pp. 79-97.
P.M. Fearnside, ‘Global warming and tropical land-use change: greenhouse gas
emissions from biomass burning, decomposition and soils in forest conversion,
shifting cultivation and secondary vegetation,’ Climatic Change, vol. 46, nos.
1-2(2000b), pp. 115-158.
P. M. Fearnside,
(2000c) ‘Greenhouse gas emissions from land-use change in Brazil's Amazon
region,’ pp. 231-249 In: R. Lal, J.M. Kimble and B.A. Stewart (eds.) Global Climate Change and Tropical
Ecosystems. Advances in Soil Science. (Boca Raton, Florida, U.S.A.: CRC
Press), 438 pp.
P.M. Fearnside, ‘Saving tropical forests as a global warming countermeasure: An issue
that divides the environmental movement,’ Ecological
Economics, vol. 39, no. 2(2001a), pp. 167-184.
P.M. Fearnside, The potential of Brazil's forest sector for mitigating global warming
under the Kyoto Protocol. Mitigation
and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change, vol. 6, nos. 3-4(2001b),
pp.355-372.
P.M. Fearnside, ‘Environmentalists split over Kyoto and Amazonian deforestation,’ Environmental
Conservation, vol. 28, no. 4(2001c),
pp. 295-299.
P.M. Fearnside, ‘Soybean cultivation as a threat to the
environment in Brazil,’ Environmental
Conservation, vol. 28, no. 1(2001d),
pp. 23-38.
P.M. Fearnside, ‘Avança Brasil: Environmental and social
consequences of Brazil’s planned infrastructure in Amazonia,’ Environmental Management vol. 30(2002a.), pp. 748-763.
P.M. Fearnside, ‘Greenhouse
gas emissions from a hydroelectric reservoir (Brazil’s Tucuruí Dam) and the
energy policy implications,’ Water, Air
and Soil Pollution, vol. 133, nos. 1-4(2002b), pp. 69-96.
P.M. Fearnside, ‘Time
preference in global warming calculations: A proposal for a unified index,’ Ecological Economics,
vol. 41, no. 1(2002c),
pp. 21-31.
P.M. Fearnside, ‘Why a 100-year time horizon should be used for
global warming mitigation calculations,’ Mitigation
and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change, vol. 7, no. 1(2002d.), pp.
19-30.
P.M. Fearnside,
‘Deforestation control in Mato Grosso: A new model for slowing the loss of
Brazil’s Amazon forest’, Ambio, vol.
32, no. 5(2003), pp. 343-345.
P.M. Fearnside, ‘A água de São Paulo e a floresta amazônica,’. Ciência Hoje (2004a) (in press).
P.M. Fearnside, (2004b), ‘Mitigation of
climatic change in the Amazon,’ In: W.F. Laurance and C.A. Peres (eds.) Emerging Threats to Tropical Forests. (Chicago, IL, U.S.A.: University of Chicago
Press) (forthcoming).
P.M. Fearnside and R.I. Barbosa, ‘Soil carbon changes from
conversion of forest to pasture in Brazilian Amazonia,’ Forest Ecology and Management, vol. 108, nos. 1-2(1998),
pp.147-166.
P.M. Fearnside and R.I. Barbosa, ‘Avoided deforestation in
Amazonia as a global warming mitigation measure: The case of Mato Grosso,’ World Resource Review, vol. 15, no. 3(2003), pp. 352-361.
P.M.
Fearnside and R.I. Barbosa, ‘Accelerating deforestation in Brazilian Amazonia:
Towards answering open questions,’ Environmental
Conservation, vol. 31, no. 1(2004) (in press)
P.M. Fearnside and W.M. Guimarães, ‘Carbon uptake by secondary
forests in Brazilian Amazonia,’ Forest
Ecology and Management, vol. 80, nos. 1-3(1996),
pp. 35-46.
P.M. Fearnside and W.F.
Laurance, ‘Comment on
“Determination of deforestation rates of the world’s humid tropical forests”,’ Science, vol. 299(2003), p. 1015.
P.M. Fearnside and W.F. Laurance, ‘Tropical
deforestation and greenhouse gas emissions. Ecological
Applications (2004) (in press).
P.M. Fearnside, N. Leal Filho and F.M. Fernandes. ‘Rainforest burning and the global carbon budget: Biomass, combustion efficiency and charcoal formation in the Brazilian Amazon,’ Journal of Geophysical Research vol. 98, no. D9(1993), pp. 16,733-16,743.
Folha de São Paulo. ‘Itamaraty atuou nos bastidores para tentar evitar isolamento do presidente Fujimori no cenário internacional: Governo brasileiro tentou legitimar "rerreeleição",’ (28 May 2000), p. A23.
Greenpeace International,
(2000), Cheating the Kyoto Protocol: Loopholes and environmental effectiveness.
(Amsterdam, the Netherlands:
Greenpeace International), 16 pp.
H. Herzog, K. Caldeira and J.
Reilly, ‘An issue of permanence: Assessing the effectiveness of temporary
carbon storage,’ Climatic Change
59(2003), pp. 293-310.
J. T Houghton, Y. Ding, D.G. Griggs, M. Noguer, R.J. Van der Linden and
D. Xiausu (eds.), (2001), Climate Change 2001: The Scientific Basis.
(Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press), 944 pp.
R.J.A. Houghton, K.T. Lawrence, J.L. Hackler and S. Brown. ‘The
spatial distribution of forest biomass in the Brazilian Amazon: A comparison of
estimates,’ Global Change Biology vol. 7(2001), pp. 731-746.
ISTOÉ [São Paulo], “A versão do Brasil,” (15 October 1997), p. 98.
J. Leggett (ed.), (1990), Global Warming: The Greenpeace Report. (Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press), 554 pp.
“Manifestação da
sociedade civil brasileira sobre as relações entre florestas e mudanças
climáticas e as expectativas para a COP-6, Belém,
24 de outubro de 2000,” (2000),
Instituto de Pesquisa Ambiental da Amazônia (IPAM), Belém, Brazil. 2 pp. (available at http://www.ipam.org.br/polamb/manbelem.htm.).
M. Meinshausen and B.
Hare. (2000), Temporary sinks do not cause
permanent climate benefits. (Amsterdam, the Netherlands: Greenpeace
International), 7 pp. (available at www.carbonsinks.de).
M. Monzoni, A. Muggiatti and R.
Smeraldi, (2000), Mudança Climática:
Tomando posições. (São Paulo, Brazil: Friends of the Earth/Amigos da Terra,
Programa Amazônia), 41 pp. (available at
http://www.amazonia.org.br/ef/Mudanca%20Climatica.pdf).
N. Myers, (1989), Deforestation
Rates in Tropical Forests and their Climatic Implications. (London, UK:
Friends of the Earth), 116 pp.
N. Myers, (1990),
‘Tropical forests,’ pp. 372-399 In: J. Leggett (ed.) Global Warming: the Greenpeace Report, (Oxford, UK: Oxford
University Press), 554 pp.
H. Nascimento and W. F. Laurance. ‘Total
aboveground biomass in central Amazonian rainforest: A landscape-scale study,’ Forest Ecology and Management, vol.
168(2002), pp. 311-321.
M.O’M. Sheehan,
(2001) City limits: Putting the brakes on
urban sprawl. Worldwatch Paper 156, (Washington, DC, U.S.A.: Worldwatch Institute),
85 pp.
UN-FCCC
(United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change), (1992), United Nations
Framework Convention on Climate Change. (available in English at http://www.unfccc.de and in
Portuguese at http://www.mct.gov.br).
UN-FCCC
(United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change), (1997), Kyoto Protocol
to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, Document
FCCC/CP/1997;7/Add1 (available in English at http://www.unfccc.de and in
Portuguese at http://www.mct.gov.br).
O.P.R.Van Vliet, A.P.C. Faaij and
C. Dieperink.. ‘Forestry projects under the Clean Development Mechanism? Modelling
of the Uncertainties in carbon mitigation and related costs of plantation
forestry projects,’ Climatic Change,
vol. 61 nos. 1-2(2003), pp. 123-156.
E.O. Wilson,
(1992) The Diversity of Life,
(Cambridge, MA, U.S.A.: Belknap/Harvard University Press), 424 pp.
World Bank, (1992), Rain Forest Trust Fund
Resolution, Background note, Part I, Introduction and Objectives, (Washington,
DC, U.S.A.: World Bank) (available at http://www.worldbank.org).
WWF Climate Change
Campaign, (2000), Make-or-break the Kyoto Protocol, (Washington, DC, U.S.A.:
World Wildlife Fund-US) (available at: http://www.panda.org/climate).
Table 1: Emissions from Amazonian
deforestation
1988-1994
2002
Deforestation
rate in Legal Amazon 15.2 25.5
(thousand km2/year)
Net
Committed Emissions from deforestation in Legal Amazon (million
t CO2-equiv. C/year)
Low trace-gas scenario 258 432
Midpoint 264 442
High trace-gas scenario 270 451
Brazilian
inventory (Amazon deforestation) 117
Approximate
discrepancy
56%
Table 2: Government positions on the Clean Development
Mechanism(a)
Plantations Agro-
Avoided
forestry
deforestation
Brazil + + -
Umbrella Group
(USA, Canada, Japan, Australia, New Zealand) + + +
European Union - - -
AOSIS (Association of
Small Island States) - - -
G-77 + China ? ? ?
(a) Plus sign
indicates favoring inclusion, minus sign opposing, and blank indicates no
position.
Table 3: Gasoline prices(a)
Country |
Price (US$/litre) |
Brazil |
0.92 |
U.SA. |
0.41 |
Canada |
0.50 |
UK |
1.13 |
France |
0.96 |
Italy |
0.95 |
Germany |
0.92 |
Spain |
0.73 |
(a) Prices in October
2000 from Sheehan (2001).
Table 4: NGO positions on
the Clean Development Mechanism
Plantations Agro-
Avoided
forestry deforestation
A.) International NGOs
Greenpeace-International - - -
WWF-International
- - -
FOE-International
- - -
Birdlife International
- - -
Climate Action Network - - -
Indigenous People's Forum
on Climate Change
- - -
B.) US NGOs
National and
US-headquartered NGOs
EDF (Environmental
Defense)
+ +
CI (Conservation
International)
+ +
TNC (The Nature
Conservancy)
+ +
NRDC (Natural Resources Defense Council) + +
UCS (Union of
Concerned Scientists)
+ +
Branches or
affiliates of International NGOs
WWF-US - - -
FOE-US - - -
C.) Brazilian NGOs
National NGOs
CNS (National Council of
Rubber Tappers)
+ +
GTA (Amazonian Working Group)
+ +
COIAB (Coordinating
Body of Indigenous
Peoples of Brazilian Amazonia) + +
FETAGRI (Federation of
Agricultural
Workers of Pará)
+ +
CPT (Pastoral Land
Commission)
+ +
IMAZON (Institute for Man and the
Environment in Amazonia)
+ +
IPAM (Institute of
Environmental
Research of Amazonia)
+ +
ISA (Socio-Environmental Institute)
+ +
Vitae Civilis (Institute for Development,
Environment and Peace - - -
Branches or
affiliates of International NGOs
Friends of the
Earth--Brazilian Amazonia + +
Friends of the
Earth--Porto Alegre - - -
Greenpeace-São Paulo - - -
WWF-Brazil - - -
(a) Plus sign
indicates favoring inclusion, minus sign opposing, and blank indicates no
position. Often, NGOs that support avoided deforestation and agroforestry and
do not have positions on silvicultural plantations would be likely to oppose
many plantation projects on the basis of their environmental and social impacts
(not on the basis of carbon accounting).
The G-77 + China does not have a unified position.